Mathematical Economics - Term Paper
- Join
- Search
- Browse
- Writing Tools
- Essay Checker
- Essay Rewriter
- Grammar Checker
In: Other Topics
Submitted By shyamshahWords 33068Pages 133 Lecture Notes on Mathematics for Economists Chien-Fu CHOU September 2006 Contents Lecture 1 Lecture 2 Lecture 3 Lecture 4 Lecture 5 Lecture 6 Lecture 7 Lecture 8 Lecture 9 Lecture 10 Static Economic Models and The Concept of Equilibrium Matrix Algebra Vector Space and Linear Transformation Determinant, Inverse Matrix, and Cramer’s rule Differential Calculus and Comparative Statics Comparative Statics – Economic applications Optimization Optimization–multivariate case Optimization with equality constraints and Nonlinear Programming General Equilibrium and Game Theory 1 5 10 16 25 36 44 61 74 89 1 1 Static Economic Models and The Concept of Equilibrium Here we use three elementary examples to illustrate the general structure of an economic model. 1.1 Partial market equilibrium model A partial market equilibrium model is constructed to explain the determination of the price of a certain commodity. The abstract form of the model is as follows. Qd = D(P ; a) Qd : Qs : P: a: Qs = S(P ; a) Qd = Qs , quantity demanded of the commodity quantity supplied to the market market price of the commodity a factor that affects demand and supply D(P ; a): demand function S(P ; a): supply function Equilibrium: A particular state that can be maintained. Equilibrium conditions: Balance of forces prevailing in the model. Substituting the demand and supply functions, we have D(P ; a) = S(P ; a). For a given a, we can solve this last equation to obtain the equilibrium price P ∗ as a function of a. Then we can study how a affects the market equilibrium price by inspecting the function. Example: D(P ; a) = a2 /P , S(P ) = 0.25P . a2 /P ∗ = 0.25P ∗ ⇒ P ∗ = 2a, Q∗ = Q∗ = s d 0.5a. 1.2 General equilibrium model Usually, markets for different commodities are interrelated. For example, the price of personal computers is strongly influenced by the situation in the market of microprocessors, the price of chicken meat is related to the supply of pork, etc. Therefore, we have to analyze interrelated markets within the same model to be able to capture such interrelationship and the partial equilibrium model is extended to the general equilibrium model. In microeconomics, we even attempt to include every commodity (including money) in a general equilibrium model. Qd1 = D1 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) Qd2 = D2 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) . . . Qdn = Dn (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) Qsn = Sn (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) Qs2 = S2 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) Qs1 = S1 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) Qdn = Qsn Qd2 = Qs2 Qd1 = Qs1 Qdi : quantity demanded of commodity i Qsi : quantity supplied of commodity i Pi : market price of commodity i a: a factor that affects the economy Di (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a): demand function of commodity i Si (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a): supply function of commodity i We have three variables and three equations for each commodity/market. 2 Substituting the demand and supply functions, we have D1 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) − S1 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) ≡ E1 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) = 0 D2 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) − S2 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) ≡ E2 (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) = 0 . . . . . . Dn (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) − Sn (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) ≡ En (P1 , . . . , Pn ; a) = 0. For a given a, it is a simultaneous equation in (P1 , . . . , Pn ). There are n equations and n unknown. In principle, we can solve the simultaneous equation to find the ∗ ∗ equilibrium prices (P1 , . . . , Pn ). A 2-market linear model: D1 = a0 + a1 P1 + a2 P2 , S1 = b0 + b1 P1 + b2 P2 , D2 = α0 + α1 P1 + α2 P2 , S2 = β0 + β1 P1 + β2 P2 . (a0 − b0 ) + (a1 − b1 )P1 + (a2 − b2 )P2 = 0 (α0 − β0 ) + (α1 − β1 )P1 + (α2 − β2 )P2 = 0. 1.3 National income model The most fundamental issue in macroeconomics is the determination of the national income of a country. C I Y S = = = = a + bY (a > 0, 0 < b < 1) I(r) ¯ C +I +G Y − C. C: Consumption Y : National income I: Investment S: Savings ¯ G: government expenditure r: interest rate a, b: coefficients of the consumption function. To solve the model, we substitute the first two equations into the third to obtain ¯ ¯ Y = a + bY + I0 + G ⇒ Y ∗ = (a + I(r) + G)/(1 − b). 1.4 The ingredients of a model We set up economic models to study economic phenomena (cause-effect relationships), or how certain economic variables affect other variables. A model consists of equations, which are relationships among variables. Variables can be divided into three categories: Endogenous variables: variables we choose to represent different states of a model. Exogenous variables: variables assumed to affect the endogenous variables but are not affected by them. Causes (Changes in exogenous var.) ⇒ Effects (Changes in endogenous var.) Parameters: Coefficients of the equations. 3 End. Var. P , Qd , Qs Pi , Qdi , Qsi C, Y , I, S Ex. Var. a a ¯ r, G Parameters Coefficients of D(P ; a), S(P ; a) a, b Partial equilibrium model: General equilibrium model: Income model: Equations can be divided into three types: Behavioral equations: representing the decisions of economic agents in the model. Equilibrium conditions: the condition such that the state can be maintained (when different forces/motivations are in balance). Definitions: to introduce new variables into the model. Behavioral equations Equilibrium cond. Definitions Partial equilibrium model: Qd = D(P ; a), Qs = S(P ; a) Qd = Qs General equilibrium model: Qdi = Di (P1 , . . . , Pn ), Qdi = Qsi Qsi = Si (P1 , . . . , Pn ) ¯ Income model: C = a + bY , I = I(r) Y =C +I +G S =Y −C 1.5 The general economic model Assume that there are n endogenous variables and m exogenous variables. Endogenous variables: x1 , x2 , . . . , xn Exogenous variables: y1 , y2 , . . . , ym. There should be n equations so that the model can be solved. F1 (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ; y1, y2 , . . . , ym ) = 0 F2 (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ; y1, y2 , . . . , ym ) = 0 . . . Fn (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ; y1 , y2 , . . . , ym) = 0. Some of the equations are behavioral, some are equilibrium conditions, and some are definitions. In principle, given the values of the exogenous variables, we solve to find the endogenous variables as functions of the exogenous variables: x1 = x1 (y1 , y2 , . . . , ym ) x2 = x1 (y1 , y2 , . . . , ym ) . . . xn = x1 (y1 , y2 , . . . , ym ). If the equations are all linear in (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ), then we can use Cramer’s rule (to be discussed in the next part) to solve the equations. However, if some equations are nonlinear, it is usually very difficult to solve the model. In general, we use comparative statics method (to be discussed in part 3) to find the differential relationships between ∂x xi and yj : ∂yji . 4 1.6 Problems Qd = 3 − P 2 , 1. Find the equilibrium solution of the following model: Qs = 6P − 4, Qs = Qd . 2. The demand and supply functions of a two-commodity model are as follows: Qd1 = 18 − 3P1 + P2 Qs1 = −2 + 4P1 Qd2 = 12 + P1 − 2P2 Qs2 = −2 + 3P2 Find the equilibrium of the model. 3. (The effect of a sales tax) Suppose that the government imposes a sales tax of t dollars per unit on product 1. The partial market model becomes Qd = D(P1 + t), 1 Qs = S(P1 ), 1 Qd = Qs . 1 1 Eliminating Qd and Qs , the equilibrium price is determined by D(P1 + t) = 1 1 S(P1 ). (a) Identify the endogenous variables and exogenous variable(s). (b) Let D(p) = 120 − P and S(p) = 2P . Calculate P1 and Q1 both as function of t. (c) If t increases, will P1 and Q1 increase or decrease? 4. Let the national-income Y = C = G = (a) (b) (c) (d) model be: C + I0 + G a + b(Y − T0 ) gY (a > 0, 0 < b < 1) (0 < g < 1) Identify the endogenous variables. Give the economic meaning of the parameter g. Find the equilibrium national income. What restriction(s) on the parameters is needed for an economically reasonable solution to exist? C = 25 + 6Y 1/2 , 5. Find the equilibrium Y and C from the following: Y = C + I0 + G0 , I0 = 16, G0 = 14. 6. In a 2-good market equilibrium model, the inverse demand functions are given by −2 −2 1 1 3 3 P1 = Q13 Q2 , P2 = Q1 Q23 . (a) Find the demand functions Q1 = D 1 (P1 , P2 ) and Q2 = D 2 (P1 , P2 ). (b) Suppose that the supply functions are Q1 = a−1 P1 , Q2 = P2 . ∗ ∗ Find the equilibrium prices (P1 , P2 ) and quantities (Q∗ , Q∗ ) as functions 1 2 of a. 5 2 Matrix Algebra There are n columns each with m elements or m rows each with n elements. We say that the size of A is m × n. If m = n, then A is a square matrix. A m × 1 matrix is called a column vector and a 1 × n matrix is called a row vector. A 1 × 1 matrix is just a number, called a scalar number. 2.1 Matrix operations A matrix is a two dimensional rectangular array of numbers: a11 a12 . . . a1n a21 a22 . . . a2n A≡ . . . .. . . . . . . . am1 am2 . . . amn Equality: A = B ⇒ (1) size(A) = size(B), (2) aij = bij for all ij. Addition/subtraction: A + B and A − B can be defined only when size(A) = size(B), in that case, size(A + B) = size(A − B) = size(A) = size(B) and (A + B)ij = aij + bij , (A − B)ij = aij − bij . For example, A= 1 2 3 4 , B= 1 0 0 1 ⇒A+B = 2 2 3 5 , A−B = 0 2 3 3 . Scalar multiplication: The multiplication of a scalar number α and a matrix A, denoted by αA, is always defined with size (αA) = size(A) and (αA)ij = αaij . For 1 2 4 8 example, A = , ⇒ 4A = . 3 4 12 16 Multiplication of two matrices: Let size(A) = m × n and size(B) = o × p, the multiplication of A and B, C = AB, is more complicated. (1) it is not always defined. (2) AB = BA even when both are defined. The condition for AB to be meaningful is that the number of columns of A should be equal to the number of rows of B, i.e., n = o. In that case, size (AB) = size (C) = m × p. a11 a12 . . . a1n b11 b12 . . . b1p c11 c12 . . . c1p a21 a22 . . . a2n b21 b22 . . . a2p c21 c22 . . . c2p A= . . . . .. . ⇒C = . . .. . .. . . , B = . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . am1 am2 . . . amn bn1 bn2 . . . anp cm1 cm2 . . . cmp where cij = Examples: 1 2 3 4 n k=1 aik bkj . , 1 2 3 3+8 11 = = , 0 5 4 0 + 20 20 5 6 5 + 14 6 + 16 19 22 = = 7 8 15 + 28 18 + 32 43 50 , 6 1 2 = 3 4 1 2 Notice that 3 4 2.2 5 6 7 8 5 + 18 10 + 24 7 + 24 14 + 32 5 6 5 6 = 7 8 7 8 23 34 31 46 1 2 . 3 4 = . Matrix representation of a linear simultaneous equation system A linear simultaneous equation system: a11 x1 + . . . + a1n xn = b1 . . . . . . an1 x1 + . . . + ann xn = bn a1n x1 b1 . , x ≡ . and b ≡ . . Then the equation . . . . . . ann xn bn the simultaneous equation system. a11 . . . . .. Define A ≡ . . . an1 . . . Ax = b is equivalent to Linear 2-market model: E1 = (a1 − b1 )p1 + (a2 − b2 )p2 + (a0 − b0 ) = 0 E2 = (α1 − β1 )p1 + (α2 − β2 )p2 + (α0 − β0 ) = 0 ⇒ a1 − b1 a2 − b2 α1 − β1 α2 − β2 p1 p2 + a0 − b0 α0 − β0 = 0 0 . Income determination model: In the algebra of real numbers, the solution to the equation ax = b is x = a−1 b. In matrix algebra, we wish to define a concept of A−1 for a n × n matrix A so that x = A−1 b is the solution to the equation Ax = b. 2.3 Commutative, association, and distributive laws C = a + bY 1 0 −b C a I = I(r) ⇒ 0 1 0 I = I(r) . Y =C +I 1 1 −1 Y 0 The notations for some important sets are given by the following table. N = nature numbers 1, 2, 3, . . . I = integers . . . , −2, −1, 0, 1, 2, . . . m R = real numbers Q = rational numbers n Rn = n-dimensional column vectors M(m, n) = m × n matrices M(n) = n × n matrices A binary operation is a law of composition of two elements from a set to form a third element of the same set. For example, + and × are binary operations of real numbers R. Another important example: addition and multiplication are binary operations of matrices. 7 Commutative law of + and × in R: a + b = b + a and a × b = b × a for all a, b ∈ R. Association law of + and × in R: (a + b) + c = a + (b + c) and (a × b) × c = a × (b × c) for all a, b, c ∈ R. Distributive law of + and × in R: (a+b)×c = a×c+b×c and c×(a+b) = c×a+c×b for all a, b, c ∈ R. The addition of matrices satisfies both commutative and associative laws: A + B = B + A and (A + B) + C = A + (B + C) for all A, B, C ∈ M(m, n). The proof is trivial. In an example, we already showed that the matrix multiplication does not satisfy the commutative law AB = BA even when both are meaningful. Nevertheless the matrix multiplication satisfies the associative law (AB)C = A(BC) when the sizes are such that the multiplications are meaningful. However, this deserves a proof! It is also true that matrix addition and multiplication satisfy the distributive law: (A + B)C = AC + BC and C(A + B) = CA + CB. You should try to prove these statements as exercises. 2.4 Special matrices In the space of real numbers, 0 and 1 are very special. 0 is the unit element of + and 1 is the unit element of ×: 0 + a = a + 0 = a, 0 × a = a × 0 = 0, and 1 × a = a × 1 = a. In matrix algebra, we define zero matrices and identity matrices as 1 0 ... 0 0 ... 0 0 1 ... 0 . .. . Om,n ≡ . . . In ≡ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 0 ... 0 0 0 ... 1 Clearly, O+A = A+O = A, OA = AO = O, and IA = AI = A. In the multiplication 1 0 0 0 0 0 of real numbers if a, b = 0 then a×b = 0. However, = = 0 0 0 1 0 0 O2,2 . Idempotent matrix: If AA = A (A must be square), then A is an idempotent matrix. 0.5 0.5 Both On,n and In are idempotent. Another example is A = . 0.5 0.5 Transpose of a matrix: For a matrix A with size m × n, we define its transpose A′ as a matrix with size n × m such that the ij-th element of A′ is equal to the ji-th element of A, a′ij = aji . 1 4 1 2 3 A= then A′ = 2 5 . 4 5 6 3 6 Properties of matrix transposition: (1) (A′ )′ = A, (2) (A + B)′ = A′ + B ′ , (3) (AB)′ = B ′ A′ . Symmetrical matrix: If A = A′ (A must be square), then A is symmetrical. The 8 condition for A to be symmetrical is that aij = aji . Both On,n and In are symmetrical. 1 2 Another example is A = . 2 3 Projection matrix: A symmetrical idempotent matrix is a projection matrix. Diagonal matrix: A symmetrical matrix A is diagonal if aij = 0 for all i = j. Both λ1 0 0 In and On,n are diagonal. Another example is A = 0 λ2 0 0 0 λ3 2.5 Inverse of a square matrix We are going to define the inverse of a square matrix A ∈ M(n). Scalar: aa−1 = a−1 a = 1 ⇒ if b satisfies ab = ba = 1 then b = a−1 . Definition of A−1 : If there exists a B ∈ M(n) such that AB = BA = In , then we define A−1 = B. −1 Examples: (1) Since II = I, I −1 = I. (2) On,n B = On,n ⇒ On,n does not exist. (3) a1 0 a−1 0 1 If A = , a1 , a2 = 0, then A−1 = . (4) If a1 = 0 or a2 = 0, 0 a2 0 a−1 2 then A−1 does not exist. Singular matrix: A square matrix whose inverse matrix does not exist. Non-singular matrix: A is non-singular if A−1 exists. Properties of matrix inversion: Let A, B ∈ M(n), (1) (A−1 )−1 = A, (2) (AB)−1 = B −1 A−1 , (3) (A′ )−1 = (A−1 )′ . 2.6 Problems 1. Let A = I − X(X ′X)−1 X ′ . (a) If the dimension of X is m × n, what must be the dimension of I and A. (b) Show that matrix A is idempotent. 2. Let A and B be n × n matrices and I be the identity matrix. (a) (A + B)3 = ? (b) (A + I)3 = ? 3. Let B = 0.5 0.5 , U = (1, 1)′, V = (1, −1)′ , and W = aU + bV , where 0.5 0.5 a and b are real numbers. Find BU, BV , and BW . Is B idempotent? 4. Suppose A is a n × n nonsingular matrix and P is a n × n idempotent matrix. Show that AP A−1 is idempotent. 5. Suppose that A and B are n × n symmetric idempotent matrices and AB = B. Show that A − B is idempotent. 6. Calculate (x1 , x2 ) 3 2 2 5 x1 x2 . 9 1 0 0 1 0 1 −1 0 7. Let I = and J = . (b) Make use of the above result to calculate J 3 , J 4 , and J −1 . (c) Show that (aI + bJ)(cI + dJ) = (ac − bd)I + (ad + bc)J. 1 (d) Show that (aI + bJ)−1 = 2 (aI − bJ) and [(cos θ)I + (sin θ)J]−1 = a + b2 (cos θ)I − (sin θ)J. (a) Show that J 2 = −I. 10 3 Vector Space and Linear Transformation In the last section, we regard a matrix simply as an array of numbers. Now we are going to provide some geometrical meanings to a matrix. (1) A matrix as a collection of column (row) vectors (2) A matrix as a linear transformation from a vector space to another vector space 3.1 Vector space, linear combination, and linear independence Each point in the m-dimensional Euclidean space can be represented as a m-dimensional v1 . column vector v = . , where each vi represents the i-th coordinate. Two points . vm in the m-dimensional Euclidean space can be added according to the rule of matrix addition. A point can be multiplied by a scalar according to the rule of scalar multiplication. v1 w1 v1 + w1 . . . . Vector addition: . + . = . . . . vm w vm + wm m v1 αv1 . . Scalar multiplication: α . = . . . . vm αvm x2 T v2 0 v 1 Q 1 2 v +v 0 x2 T E x1 v E x1 2v With such a structure, we say that the m-dimensional Euclidean space is a vector space. 11 m m-dimensional column vector space: R = v1 . , v ∈ R . . i . vm We use superscripts to represent individual vectors. A m × n matrix: a collection of n m-dimensional column vectors: a11 a11 a12 . . . a1n a12 a1n a21 a22 . . . a2n a21 a22 a2n . . . .. . . . = . , . , . . . , . . . . . . . . . . . a am1 am2 . . . amn am2 amn m1 Linear combination of a collection of vectors {v , . . . , v }: w = (α1 , . . . , αn ) = (0, . . . , 0). 1 n n αi v i , where i=1 Linear dependence of {v 1 , . . . , v n }: If one of the vectors is a linear combination of others, then the collection is said to be linear dependent. Alternatively, the collection is linearly dependent if (0, . . . , 0) is a linear combination of it. Linear independence of {v 1 , . . . , v n }: If the collection is not linear dependent, then it is linear independent. a1 0 0 Example 1: v 1 = 0 , v 2 = a2 , v 3 = 0 , a1 a2 a3 = 0. 0 0 a3 If α1 v 1 + α2 v 2 + α3 v 3 = 0 then (α1 , α2 , α3 ) = (0, 0, 0). Therefore, {v 1 , v 2 , v 3 } must be linear independent. 1 4 7 1 2 , v 2 = 5 , v 3 = 8 . Example 2: v = 3 6 9 2 1 3 1 2 3 , is 2v = v + v . Therefore, {v , v v } linear dependent. 1 4 Example 3: v 1 = 2 , v 2 = 5 . 6 3 0 α1 + 4α2 α1 v 1 + α2 v 2 = 2α1 + 5α2 = 0 ⇒ α1 = α2 = 0. Therefore, {v 1 , v 2 } is 0 3α1 + 6α2 linear independent. Span of {v 1 , . . . , v n }: The space of linear combinations. If a vector is a linear combination of other vectors, then it can be removed without changing the span. 12 v11 . . . v1n . . ≡ Dimension(Span{v 1 , . . . , v n }) = Maximum # of indepen.. . Rank . . . . vm1 . . . vmn dent vectors. 3.2 Linear transformation Consider a m × n matrix A. Given x ∈ Rn , Ax ∈ Rm . Therefore, we can define a linear transformation from Rn to Rm as f (x) = Ax or y1 a11 . . . a1n . . . .. . f : Rn →Rm , f (x) = . = . . . . . ym am1 . . . amn x1 . . . . xn It is linear because f (αx + βw) = A(αx + βw) = αAx + βAw = αf (x) + βf (w). 0 0 1 0 1 0 Standard basis vectors of Rn : e1 ≡ . , e2 ≡ . , . . . , en ≡ . . . . . . . . 1 0 0 a1i . i i Let v be the i-th column of A, v = . . . ami a11 . . . a1n 1 a11 . . ⇒ v 1 = f (e1 ) = Ae1 , etc. .. i i ... = . . . v = f (e ): . . . . . am1 0 am1 . . . amn Therefore, v i is the image of the i-th standard basis vector ei under f . Span{v 1 , . . . , v n } = Range space of f (x) = Ax ≡ R(A). Rank(A) ≡ dim(R(A)). Null space of f (x) = Ax: N(A) ≡ {x ∈ Rn , f (x) = Ax = 0}. dim(R(A)) + dim(N(A)) = n. Example 1: A = Example 2: B = Rank(B) = 1. 1 0 1 1 0 . N(A) = 2 1 . N(B) = 1 0 0 k −k , R(A) = R2 , Rank(A) = 2. , k ∈ R , R(B) = k k ,k ∈ R , The multiplication of two matrices can be interpreted as the composition of two linear transformations. f : Rn →Rm , f (x) = Ax, g : Rp →Rn , g(y) = By, ⇒ f (g(x)) = A(By), f ◦g : Rp →Rm . 13 The composition is meaningful only when the dimension of the range space of g(y) is equal to the dimension of the domain of f (x), which is the same condition for the validity of the matrix multiplication. Every linear transformation f : Rn →Rm can be represented by f (x) = Ax for some m × n matrix. 3.3 Inverse transformation and inverse of a square matrix Remark: On,n represents the mapping that maps every point to the origin. In represents the identity mapping that maps a point to itself. A projection matrix repre0.5 0.5 sents a mapping that projects points onto a linear subspace of Rn , eg., 0.5 0.5 projects points onto the 45 degree line. d x d d d Ax d d d d d d E x1 s d d d d d d d d T Consider now the special case of square matrices. Each A ∈ M(n) represents a linear transformation f : Rn →Rn . The definition of the inverse matrix A−1 is such that AA−1 = A−1 A = I. If we regard A as a linear transformation from Rn →Rn and I as the identity transformation that maps every vector (point) into itself, then A−1 is the inverse mapping of A. If dim(N(A)) = 0, then f (x) is one to one. If dim(R(A)) = n, then R(A) = Rn and f (x) is onto. ⇒ if Rank(A) = n, then f (x) is one to one and onto and there exits an inverse mapping f −1 : Rn →Rn represented by a n×n square matrix A−1 . f −1 f (x) = x ⇒ A−1 Ax = x. ⇒ if Rank(A) = n, then A is non-singular. if Rank(A) < n, then f (x) is not onto, no inverse mapping exists, and A is singular. a1 0 0 1 4 7 Examples: Rank 0 a2 0 = 3 and Rank 2 5 8 = 2. 0 0 a3 3 6 9 x2 x= Ax = x′ = 1 2 .5 .5 1 .5 .5 2 k , Ax′ = −k = 0 0 1.5 1.5 14 3.4 Problems 0 1 0 1. Let B = 0 0 1 0 0 0 and TB the corresponding linear transformation TB : R3 → R3 , TB (x) = Bx, x1 where x = x2 ∈ R3 . x3 a (a) Is v 1 = 0 , a = 0, in the null space of TB ? Why or why not? 0 0 (b) Is v 2 = 0 , b = 0, in the range space of TB ? Why or why not? How b c 3 d ? about v = 0 (c) Find Rank(B). 2. Let A be an idempotent matrix. (a) Show that I − A is also idempotent. (b) Suppose that x = 0 is in the null space of A, i.e., Ax = 0. Show that x must be in the range space of I − A, i.e., show that there exists a vector y such that (I − A)y = x. (Hint: Try y = x.) (c) Suppose that y is in the range space of A. Show that y must be in the null space of I − A. (d) Suppose that A is n × n and Rank[A] = n − k, n > k > 0. What is the rank of I − A? 1 1 1 1 0 0 1 1 3 3 3 0 1 0 , A = 1 1 1 , x = a , y = α , and 3. Let I = 3 3 3 1 1 1 0 0 1 b β 3 3 3 B = I − A. (a) Calculate AA and BB. (b) If y is in the range space of A, what are the values of α and β? (c) What is the dimension of the range space of A? (d) Determine the rank of A. (e) Suppose now that x is in the null space of B. What should be the values of a and b? (f) What is the dimension of the null space of B? 15 (g) Determine the rank of B? 4. Let A = 1/5 2/5 2/5 4/5 1 1 1 and B = 0 1 1 . 0 0 1 (a) Determine the ranks of A and B. (b) Determine the null space and range space of each of A and B and explain why. (c) Determine whether they are idempotent. 16 4 Determinant, Inverse Matrix, and Cramer’s rule In this section we are going to derive a general method to calculate the inverse of a square matrix. First, we define the determinant of a square matrix. Using the properties of determinants, we find a procedure to compute the inverse matrix. Then we derive a general procedure to solve a simultaneous equation. 4.1 Permutation group A permutation of {1, 2, . . . , n} is a 1-1 mapping of {1, 2, . . . , n} onto itself, written as 1 2 ... n π= meaning that 1 is mapped to i1 , 2 is mapped to i2 , . . ., and i1 i2 . . . in n is mapped to in . We also write π = (i1 , i2 , . . . , ın ) when no confusing. Permutation set of {1, 2, . . . , n}: Pn ≡ {π = (i1 , i2 , . . . , in ) : π is a permutation}. P2 = {(1, 2), (2, 1)}. P3 = {(1, 2, 3), (1, 3, 2), (2, 1, 3), (2, 3, 1), (3, 1, 2), (3, 2, 1)}. P4 : 4! = 24 permutations. Inversions in a permutation π = (i1 , i2 , . . . , in ): If there exist k and l such that k < l and ik > il , then we say that an inversion occurs. N(i1 , i2 , . . . , ın ): Total number of inversions in (i1 , i2 , . . . , in ). Examples: 1. N(1, 2) = 0, N(2, 1) = 1. 2. N(1, 2, 3) = 0, N(1, 3, 2) = 1, N(2, 1, 3) = 1, N(2, 3, 1) = 2, N(3, 1, 2) = 2, N(3, 2, 1) = 3. 4.2 Determinant a11 a12 a21 a22 . . . . . . an1 an2 . . . a1n . . . a2n . : .. . . . . . . ann (−1)N (i1 ,i2 ,...,in ) a1i1 a2i2 . . . anin . (i1 ,i2 ,...,in )∈Pn Determinant of A = |A| ≡ a11 a12 a21 a22 n = 2: = (−1)N (1,2) a11 a22 + (−1)N (2,1) a12 a21 = a11 a22 − a12 a21 . a11 a12 a13 n = 3: a21 a22 a23 = a31 a32 a33 N (1,2,3) a11 a22 a33 + (−1)N (1,3,2) a11 a23 a32 + (−1)N (2,1,3) a12 a21 a33 (−1) (−1)N (2,3,1) a12 a23 a31 + (−1)N (3,1,2) a13 a21 a32 + (−1)N (3,2,1) a13 a22 a31 = a11 a22 a33 − a11 a23 a32 − a12 a21 a33 + a12 a23 a31 + a13 a21 a32 − a13 a22 a31 . + 17 a11 a11 n = 2: a21 a12 d d a12 d d a13 d d a11 d d d d a12 d d n = 3: a21 a31 a22 a32 a23 a33 a21 a31 a22 a32 a22 d d 4.3 Properties of determinant Property 1: |A′ | = |A|. Proof: Each term of |A′ | corresponds to a term of |A| of the same sign. By property 1, we can replace “column vectors” in the properties below by “row vectors”. Since a n × n matrix can be regarded as n column vectors A = {v 1 , v 2, . . . , v n }, we can regard determinants as a function of n column vectors |A| = D(v 1 , v 2 , . . . , v n ), D : Rn×n →R. By property 1, we can replace “column vectors” in the properties below by “row vectors”. Property 2: If two column vectors are interchanged, the determinant changes sign. Proof: Each term of the new determinant corresponds to a term of |A| of opposite sign because the number of inversion increases or decreases by 1. 2 1 1 2 = 2 × 3 − 1 × 4 = 2, = 1 × 4 − 2 × 3 = −2, Example: 4 3 3 4 Property 3: If two column vectors are identical, then the determinant is 0. Proof: By property 2, the determinant is equal to the negative of itself, which is possible only when the determinant is 0. Property 4: If you add a linear combination of other column vectors to a column vector, the determinant does not change. Proof: Given other column vectors, the determinant function is a linear function of v i : D(αv i + βw i; other vectors ) = αD(v i ; other vectors ) + βD(w i; other vectors ). 1+5×2 2 1 2 5×2 2 1 2 2 2 Example: = + = +5× = 3+5×4 4 3 4 5×4 4 3 4 4 4 1 2 + 5 × 0. 3 4 Submatrix: We denote by Aij the submatrix of A obtained by deleting the i-th row and j-th column from A. Minors: The determinant |Aij | is called the minor of the element aij . Cofactors: Cij ≡ (−1)i+j |Aij | is called the cofactor of aij . 18 n Property 5 (Laplace theorem): Given i = ¯ |A| = i, a¯ C¯ . ij ij j=1 Given j = ¯ |A| = n ai¯Ci¯. j, j i=1 j Proof: In the definition of the determinant of |A|, all terms with aij can be put togethere to become aij Cij . 1 2 3 5 6 4 6 4 5 Example: 4 5 6 = 1 × −2× +3× . 8 0 7 0 7 8 7 8 0 n Property 6: Given i = ¯ i, ′ j=1 ai′ j C¯ = 0. ij Given j ′ = ¯ = n aij ′ Ci¯ = 0. j, j i=1 Therefore, if you multiply cofactors by the elements from a different row or column, you get 0 instead of the determinant. Proof: The sum becomes the determinant of a matrix with two identical rows (columns). 5 6 4 6 4 5 Example: 0 = 4 × −5× +6× . 8 0 7 0 7 8 4.4 Computation of the inverse matrix Using properties 5 and 6, can calculate the inverse of A as follows. we C11 C12 . . . C1n C21 C22 . . . C2n 1. Cofactor matrix: C ≡ . . . . .. . . . . . . . Cn1 Cn2 . . . Cnn C11 C21 . . . Cn1 C12 C22 . . . Cn2 ′ 2. Adjoint of A: Adj A ≡ C = . . . .. . . . . . . . . C1n C2n . . . Cnn |A| 0 . . . 0 0 |A| . . . 0 1 ′ −1 3. ⇒ AC ′ = C ′ A = . . .. . ⇒ if |A| = 0 then |A| C = A . . . . . . . . 0 0 . . . |A| a11 a12 a22 −a21 Example 1: A = then C = . a21 a22 −a12 a11 1 ′ 1 a22 −a12 C = ; if |A| = a11 a22 − a12 a21 = 0. |A| a11 a22 − a12 a21 −a21 a11 1 2 3 Example 2: A = 4 5 6 ⇒ |A| = 27 = 0 and 7 8 0 5 6 4 6 4 5 C11 = = −48, C12 = − = 42, C13 = = −3, 8 0 7 0 7 8 A−1 = 19 2 3 = 24, C22 = 8 0 2 3 C31 = = −3, C32 = − 5 6 −48 42 −3 C = 24 −21 6 , C ′ −3 6 −3 C21 = − 3 1 2 = −21, C23 = − = 6, 0 7 8 3 1 2 = 6, C33 = = −3, 6 4 5 −48 24 −3 −48 24 −3 1 = 42 −21 6 , A−1 = 42 −21 6 . 27 −3 6 −3 −3 6 −3 1 7 1 4 If |A| = 0, then A is singular and A−1 does not The reason is that |A| = exist. a11 a1n 0 . . . 0 ⇒ AC ′ = 0n×n ⇒ C11 . + · · · + Cn1 . = . . The column vectors . . . an1 ann 0 of A are linear dependent, the linear transformation TA is not onto and therefore an inverse transformation does not exist. 4.5 Cramer’s rule C′ . The solution to the simultaneous |A| C ′b . |A| n |Ai | j=1 Cj bj = , where Ai is a matrix obtained by replacing Cramer’s rule: xi = |A| |A| the i-th column of A by b, Ai = {v 1 , . . . , v i−1, b, v i+1 , . . . , v n }. equation Ax = b is x = A−1 b = 4.6 Economic applications a1 − b1 a2 − b2 α1 − β1 α2 − β2 p1 p2 = b0 − a0 β0 − α0 . If |A| = 0 then A is non-singular and A−1 = Linear 2-market model: b0 − a0 a2 − b2 β0 − α0 α2 − β2 p1 = a1 − b1 a2 − b2 α1 − β1 α2 − β2 1 Income determination model: 0 1 a 0 −b I(r) 1 0 0 1 −1 , 1 0 −b 0 1 0 1 1 −1 C= I= 1 a −b 0 I(r) 0 1 0 −1 , 1 0 −b 0 1 0 1 1 −1 a1 − b1 b0 − a0 α1 − β1 β0 − α0 , p2 = . a1 − b1 a2 − b2 α1 − β1 α2 − β2 0 −b C a 1 0 I = I(r) . 1 −1 Y 0 1 0 1 1 0 1 Y = 0 a 1 I(r) 1 0 . 0 −b 1 0 1 −1 20 IS-LM model: In the income determination model, we regard interest rate as given and consider only the product market. Now we enlarge the model to include the money market and regard interest rate as the price (an endogenous variable) determined in the money market. good market: money market: C = a + bY L = kY − lR ¯ I = I0 − iR M =M ¯=Y C +I +G M =L end. var: C, I, Y , R (interest rate), L(demand for money), M (money supply) ¯ ¯ ex. var: G, M (quantity of money). parameters: a, b, i, k, l. Substitute into equilibrium conditions: good market: money market endogenous variables: ¯ ¯ a + bY + I0 − iR + G = Y , kY − lR = M, Y, R 1−b i k −l Y R = ¯ a + I0 + G ¯ M ¯ 1 − b a + I0 + G ¯ k M . 1−b i k −l Y = ¯ a + I0 + G i ¯ M −l , 1−b i k −l R= Two-country income determination model: Another extension of the income determination model is to consider the interaction between domestic country and the rest of the world (foreign country). domestic good market: foreign good market: endogenous variables: C = a + bY C ′ = a′ + b′ Y ′ C, I, Y , ′ ′ I = I0 I = I0 M (import), ′ M = M0 + mY M ′ = M0 + m′ Y ′ X (export), ′ ′ ′ ′ ′ ′ C +I +X −M =Y C +I +X −M =Y C , I ′, Y ′, M ′, X ′. By definition, X = M ′ and X ′ = M. Substituting into the equilibrium conditions, ′ ′ ′ (1 − b + m)Y − m′ Y ′ = a + I0 + M0 − M0 (1 − b′ + m′ )Y ′ − mY = a′ + I0 + M0 − M0 . 1−b+m −m′ −m 1 − b′ + m′ Y = ′ a + I0 + M0 − M0 −m′ ′ ′ ′ a + I0 + M0 − M0 1 − b′ + m′ 1−b+m −m′ −m 1 − b′ + m′ Y Y′ = ′ a + I0 + M0 − M0 ′ ′ a′ + I0 + M0 − M0 . Y′ = ′ 1 − b + m a + I0 + M0 − M0 ′ ′ ′ −m a + I0 + M0 − M0 . 1−b+m −m′ −m 1 − b′ + m′ 4.7 Input-output table Assumption: Technologies are all fixed proportional, that is, to produce one unit of product Xi , you need aji units of Xj . 21 a11 a12 . . . a1n a21 a22 . . . a2n IO table: A = . . .. . . . . . . . . . an1 an2 . . . ann Column i represents the coefficients of inputs needed to produce one unit of Xi . x1 x2 Suppose we want to produce a list of outputs x = . , we will need a list of inputs . . xn a11 x1 + a12 x2 + . . . + a1n xn a21 x2 + a22 x2 + . . . + a2n xn Ax = . The net output is x − Ax = (I − A)x. . . . an1 x1 + an2 x2 + . . . + ann xn d1 d2 If we want to produce a net amount of d = . , then since d = (I − A)x, . . dn −1 x = (I − A) d. 4.8 A geometric interpretation of determinants Because of properties 2 and 4, the determinant function D(v 1 , . . . , v n ) is called an alternative linear n-form of Rn . It is equal to the volume of the parallelepiped formed by the vectors {v 1 , . . . , v n }. For n = 2, |A| is the area of the parallelogram formed by a11 a21 , . See the diagram: a12 a22 x2 T |A| = Area of D ¢ ¢ ¢ v 2 ¢ ¢ ¢ ¢ D ¢ ¢ ¢ ¢ ¢ ¢ 1 ¢ ¢ v I ¢ ¢ ¢ E x1 If the determinant is 0, then the volume is 0 and the vectors are linearly dependent, one of them must be a linear combination of others. Therefore, an inverse mapping does not exist, A−1 does not exist, and A is singular. 22 4.9 Rank of a matrix and solutions of Ax = d when |A| = 0 Rank(A) = the maximum # of independent vectors in A = {v 1 , . . . , v n } = dim(Range Space of TA ). Rank(A) = the size of the largest non-singular square submatrices of A. 1 2 3 1 2 1 2 Examples: Rank = 2. Rank 4 5 6 = 2 because is non3 4 4 5 7 8 9 singular. Property 1: Rank(AB) ≤ min{Rank(A), Rank(B)}. Property 2: dim(Null Space of TA ) + dim(Range Space of TA ) = n. Consider the simultaneous equation Ax = d. When |A| = 0, there exists a row of A that is a linear combination of other rows . and Rank(A) < n. First, form the augmented matrix M ≡ [A. and calculate .d] the rank of M. There are two cases. Case 1: Rank(M) = Rank (A). In this case, some equations are linear combinations of others (the equations are dependent) and can be removed without changing the solution space. There will be more variables than equations after removing these equations. Hence, there will be infinite number of solutions. 1 2 x1 3 1 2 Example: = . Rank(A) = Rank = 1 = Rank(M) = 2 4 x2 6 2 4 1 2 3 Rank . 2 4 6 The second equation is just twice the first equation and can be discarded. The sox1 3 − 2k lutions are = for any k. On x1 -x2 space, the two equations are x2 k represented by the same line and every point on the line is a solution. Case 2: Rank(M) = Rank(A) + 1. In this case, there exists an equation whose LHS is a linear combination of the LHS of other equations but whose RHS is different from the same linear combination of the RHS of other equations. Therefore, the equation system is contraditory and there will be no solutions. 1 2 x1 3 1 2 Example: = . Rank(A) = Rank = 1 < Rank(M) = x2 2 4 7 2 4 1 2 3 Rank = 2. 2 4 7 Multiplying the first equation by 2, 2x1 + 4x2 = 6, whereas the second equation x1 says 2x1 + 4x2 = 7. Therefore, it is impossible to have any satisfying both x2 equations simultaneously. On x1 -x2 space, the two equations are represented by two parallel lines and cannot have any intersection points. 23 4.10 Problems 1. Suppose v1 = (1, 2, 3)′, v2 = (2, 3, 4)′, and v3 = (3, 4, 5)′. Is {v1 , v2 , v3 } linearly independent? Why or why not? 6 5 . 2.. Find the inverse of A = 8 7 2 1 6 3. Given the 3 × 3 matrix A = 5 3 4 , 8 9 7 (a) calculate the cofactors C11 , C21 , C31 , (b) use Laplace expansion theorem to find |A|, (c) and use Cramer’s rule to find X1 of the following equation system: 2 1 6 X1 1 5 3 4 X2 = 2 . 8 9 7 X3 3 (Hint: Make use of the results of (a).) 4. Use Cramer’s rule to solve the national-income model C = a + b(Y − T ) T = −t0 + t1 Y Y = C + I0 + G (1) (2) (3) 0 1 0 5. Let A = 0 0 1 . 0 0 0 (a) Find AA and AAA. (b) Let x = (1, 2, 3)′, compute Ax, AAx, and AAAx. (c) Find Rank[A], Rank[AA], and Rank[AAA]. 1 −1 6. Let X = 1 0 . 1 1 ′ (a) Find X X and (X ′ X)−1 . (b) Compute X(X ′ X)−1 X ′ and I − X(X ′ X)−1 X ′ . (c) Find Rank[X(X ′ X)−1 X ′ ] and Rank[I − X(X ′X)−1 X ′ ]. 1 2 1 2 1 1 2 4 7. A = ,B= , and C = . 3 6 3 6 1 3 6 12 (a) Find the ranks of A, B, and C. (b) Use the results of (a) to determine whether the following system has any solution: 1 2 3 6 X1 X2 = 1 1 . (c) Do the same for the following system: 1 2 3 6 X1 X2 = 4 12 . 24 3 2 , I the 2 × 2 identity matrix, and λ a scalar number. 1 2 (a) Find |A − λI|. (Hint: It is a quadratic function of λ.) (b) Determine Rank(A − I) and Rank(A − 4I). (Remark: λ = 1 and λ = 4 are the eigenvalues of A, that is, they are the roots of the equation |A − λI| = 0, called the characteristic equation of A.) (c) Solve the simultaneous equation system (A − I)x = 0 assuming that x1 = 1. (Remark: The solution is called an eigenvector of A associated with the eigenvalue λ = 1.) (d) Solve the simultaneous equation system (A − 4I)y = 0 assuming that y1 = 1. (e) Determine whether the solutions x and y are linearly independent. 8. Let A = 25 5 Differential Calculus and Comparative Statics As seen in the last chapter, a linear economic model can be represented by a matrix equation Ax = d(y) and solved using Cramer’s rule, x = A−1 d(y). On the other hand, a closed form solution x = x(y) for a nonlinear economic model is, in most applications, impossible to obtain. For general nonlinear economic models, we use differential calculus (implicit function theorem) to obtain the derivatives of endogenous variables ∂xi with respect to exogenous variables : ∂yj f1 (x1 , . . . , xn ; y1 , . . . , ym ) = 0 . . . fn (x1 , . . . , xn ; y1, . . . , ym ) = 0 ∂x1 ∂x1 ∂f1 ∂f1 ∂f1 ∂f1 ∂x1 . . . ∂xn ∂y1 . . . ∂ym ∂y1 . . . ∂ym . . . . . = − . . . .. .. .. . . . . . ⇒ . . . . . . . . . ∂fn ∂xn ∂fn ∂fn ∂xn ∂fn ... ... ... ∂x1 ∂xn ∂y1 ∂ym ∂y1 ∂ym −1 ∂x1 ∂x1 ∂f1 ∂f1 ∂f1 ∂f1 ∂x1 . . . ∂xn ∂y1 . . . ∂ym ∂y1 . . . ∂ym . . = − . . . . . .. .. .. . . . . . ⇒ . . . . . . . . . . ∂fn ∂xn ∂xn ∂fn ∂fn ∂fn ... ... ... ∂y1 ∂ym ∂x1 ∂xn ∂y1 ∂ym ∂xi ∂xi represents a cause-effect relationship. If > 0 (< 0), then xi will increase Each ∂yj ∂yj (decrease) when yj increases. Therefore, instead of computing xi = xi (y), we want to ∂xi determine the sign of for each i-j pair. In the following, we will explain how it ∂yj works. 5.1 Differential Calculus x = f (y) ⇒ f ′ (y ∗) = dx dy ≡ lim f (y ∗ + ∆y) − f (y ∗) . ∆y→0 ∆y y=y ∗ On y-x space, x = f (y) is represented by a curve and f ′ (y ∗ ) represents the slope of the tangent line of the curve at the point (y, x) = (y ∗, f (y ∗)). Basic rules: dx 1. x = f (y) = k, = f ′ (y) = 0. dy dx 2. x = f (y) = y n , = f ′ (y) = ny n−1 . dy dx 3. x = cf (y), = cf ′ (y). dy 26 4. x = f (y) + g(y), 5. x = f (y)g(y), dx = f ′ (y) + g ′ (y). dy dx = f ′ (y)g(y) + f (y)g ′(y). dy dx f ′ (y)g(y) − f (y)g ′(y) 6. x = f (y)/g(y), = . dy (g(y))2 dx dx 1 7. x = eay , = aeay . x = ln y, = . dy dy y dx dx 8. x = sin y, = cos y. x = cos y, = − sin y. dy dy Higher order derivatives: d d d2 d d2 f ′′ (y) ≡ f (y) = 2 f (y), f ′′′ (y) ≡ f (y) dy dy dy dy dy 2 5.2 Partial derivatives = d3 f (y). dy 3 In many cases, x is a function of several y’s: x = f (y1 , y2 , . . . , yn ). The partial ∗ ∗ ∗ derivative of x with respect to yi evaluated at (y1 , y2 , . . . , yn ) = (y1 , y2 , . . . , yn ) is ∂x ∂yi ∗ ∗ ∗ (y1 ,y2 ,...,yn ) ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ f (y1 , . . . , yi + ∆yi , . . . , yn ) − f (y1 , . . . , yi , . . . , yn ) ≡ lim , ∆yi →0 ∆yi that is, we regard all other independent variables as constant (f as a function of yi only) and take derivative. ∂xn xm 1 2 9. = nxn−1 xm . 1 2 ∂x1 Higher order derivatives: We can define higher order derivatives as before. For the case with two independent variables, there are 4 second order derivatives: ∂ ∂x ∂2x ∂ ∂x ∂2x ∂ ∂x ∂2x ∂ ∂x ∂2x = 2, = , = , = 2. ∂y1 ∂y1 ∂y1 ∂y2 ∂y1 ∂y2 ∂y1 ∂y1 ∂y2 ∂y1 ∂y2 ∂y2 ∂y2 ∂y2 Notations: f1 , f2 , f11 , f12 , f21 , f22 . f1 . ∇f ≡ . : Gradient vector of f . . f n f11 . . . f1n . . H(f ) ≡ . . . . . : second order derivative matrix, called Hessian of f . . . fn1 . . . fnn Equality of cross-derivatives: If f is twice continously differentiable, then fij = fji and H(f ) is symmetric. 5.3 Economic concepts similar to derivatives Elasticity of Xi w.r.t. Yj : EXi ,Yj ≡ Yj ∂Xi , the percentage change of Xi when Yj Xi ∂Yj P dQd increases by 1 %. Example: Qd = D(P ), EQd ,P = Qd dP 27 Basic rules: 1. EX1 X2 ,Y = EX1 ,Y + EX2 ,Y , 3. EY,X = 1/EX,Y . 2. EX1 /X2 ,Y = EX1 ,Y − EX2 ,Y , 1 dX Growth rate of X = X(t): GX ≡ , the percentage change of X per unit of X dt time. 5.4 Mean value and Taylor’s Theorems Continuity theorem: If f (y) is continuous on the interval [a, b] and f (a) ≤ 0, f (b) ≥ 0, then there exists a c ∈ [a, b] such that f (c) = 0. Rolle’s theorem: If f (y) is continuous on the interval [a, b] and f (a) = f (b) = 0, then there exists a c ∈ (a, b) such that f ′ (c) = 0. Mean value theorem: If f (y) is continously differentiable on [a, b], then there exists a c ∈ (a, b) such that f (b) − f (a) = f ′ (c)(b − a) or f (b) − f (a) = f ′ (c). b−a Taylor’s Theorem: If f (y) is k + 1 times continously differentiable on [a, b], then for each y ∈ [a, b], there exists a c ∈ (a, y) such that f (y) = f (a) + f ′(a)(y − a) + 5.5 f (k) (a) f (k+1) (c) f ′′ (a) (y − a)2 + . . .+ (y − a)k + (y − a)k+1 . 2! k! (k + 1)! Concepts of differentials and applications Let x = f (y). Define ∆x ≡ f (y + ∆y) − f (y), called the finite difference of x. ∆x f (y + ∆y) − f (y) ∆x Finite quotient: = ⇒ ∆x = ∆y. ∆y ∆y ∆y dx, dy: Infinitesimal changes of x and y, dx, dy > 0 (so that we can divid something by dx or by dy) but dx, dy < a for any positive real number a (so that ∆y→dy). Differential of x = f (y): dx = df = f ′ (y)dy. Chain rule: x = f (y), y = g(z) ⇒ x = f (g(z)), dx = f ′ (y)g ′(z) = f ′ (g(z))g ′(z). dz dx = 3y 2 2z = 6z(z 2 + 1)2 . Example: x = (z 2 + 1)3 ⇒ x = y 3, y = z 2 + 1 ⇒ dz Inverse function rule: x = f (y), ⇒ y = f −1 (x) ≡ g(x), dy 1 dx = f ′ (y)dy, dy = g ′(x)dx ⇒ dx = f ′ (y)g ′(x)dx. = g ′(x) = ′ . dx f (y) dx 1 1 Example: x = ln y ⇒ y = ex ⇒ = x = . dy e y dx = f ′ (y)dy, dy = g ′(z)dz ⇒ dx = f ′ (y)g ′(z)dz. 28 5.6 Concepts of total differentials and applications Let x = f (y1 , y2). Define ∆x ≡ f (y1 + ∆y1 , y2 + ∆y2 ) − f (y1, y2 ), called the finite difference of x. ∆x = f (y1 + ∆y1 , y2 + ∆y2 ) − f (y1, y2 ) = f (y1 + ∆y1 , y2 + ∆y2 ) − f (y1, y2 + ∆y2 ) + f (y1 , y2 + ∆y2 ) − f (y1 , y2) f (y1 + ∆y1 , y2 + ∆y2 ) − f (y1, y2 + ∆y2 ) f (y1, y2 + ∆y2 ) − f (y1 , y2 ) = ∆y1 + ∆y2 ∆y1 ∆y2 dx = f1 (y1 , y2 )dy1 + f2 (y1 , y2 )dy2. dy1 . dx, dy = . : Infinitesimal changes of x (endogenous), y1 , . . . , yn (exogenous). . dyn Total differential of x = f (y1 , . . . , yn ): dy1 . dx = df = f1 (y1 , . . . , yn )dy1 +. . .+fn (y1 , . . . , yn )dyn = (f1 , . . . , fn ) . = (∇f )′ dy. . dyn Implicit function rule: In many cases, the relationship between two variables are defined implicitly. For ¯ example, the indifference curve U(x1 , x2 ) = U defines a relationship between x1 and dx2 , we use implicit function rule. x2 . To find the slope of the curve dx1 U1 (x1 , x2 ) dx2 ¯ =− . dU = U1 (x1 , x2 )dx1 + U2 (x1 , x2 )dx2 = dU = 0 ⇒; dx1 U2 (x1 , x2 ) 1 1 3 3 Example: U(x1 , x2 ) = 3x1 + 3x2 = 6 defines an indifference curve passing through the point (x1 , x2 ) = (1, 1). The slope (Marginal Rate of Substitution) at (1, 1) can be calculated using implicit function rule. dx2 U1 x 3 1 =− = − 1 2 = − = −1. − dx1 U2 1 x 3 2 −2 Multivariate chain rule: x = f (y1, y2 ), y1 = g 1(z1 , z2 ), y2 = g 2 (z1 , z2 ), ⇒ x = f (g 1(z1 , z2 ), g 2(z1 , z2 )) ≡ H(z1 , z2 ). We can use the total differentials dx, dy1, dy2 to find the derivative dx = (f1 , f2 ) dy1 dy2 = (f1 , f2 ) 1 1 g1 g2 2 2 g1 g2 ∂x . ∂z1 dz1 dz2 . dz1 dz2 1 2 1 2 = (f1 g1 +f2 g1 , f1 g2 +f2 g2 ) 29 ⇒ ∂H ∂x ∂H ∂x 1 2 1 2 = = f1 g1 + f2 g1 , = = f1 g2 + f2 g2 . ∂z1 ∂z1 ∂z2 ∂z2 ∂x 5 7 6 6 = 6y1 y2 (2) + 7y1 y2 (4). ∂z1 6 7 Example: x = y1 y2 , y1 = 2z1 + 3z2 , y2 = 4z1 + 5z2 , Total derivative: x = f (y1 , y2 ), y2 = h(y1 ), x = f (y1 , h(y1 )) ≡ g(y1), dx dy1 = f1 + f2 h′ . y2 =h(y1 ) ⇒ dx = f1 dy1 + f2 dy2 = f1 dy1 + f2 h′ dy1 = (f1 + f2 h′ )dy1. Total derivative: Partial derivative (direct effect of y1 on x): Indirect effect through y2 : Example: (x1 , x2 ) is ∂x dy2 = f2 h′ . ∂y2 dy1 ∂x ∂f = = f1 (y1 , y2 ). ∂y1 ∂y1 1 3 3x2 , w.r.t. x1 along the indifference curve passing through (1, 1) is a total derivative dm dx1 5.7 d2 x2 = dx2 1 ∂m ∂m dx2 ∂m ∂m = + = + ∂x1 ∂x2 dx1 ∂x1 ∂x2 − x1 −2 3 1 3 Given the utility function U(x1 , x2 ) = 3x1 −2 dx2 U1 (x1 , x2 ) x 3 m(x1 , x2 ) = = − = − 12. − dx1 U2 (x1 , x2 ) x2 3 + the MRS at a point The rate of change of MRS 3x1 1/3 +3x2 =6 1/3 3x1 1/3 +3x2 =6 1/3 −2 x2 3 . Inverse function theorem In Lecture 3, we discussed a linear mapping x = Ay and its inverse mapping y = A−1 x when |A| = 0. x1 x2 = a11 a12 a21 a22 y1 y2 y1 y2 = a22 |A| −a21 |A| −a12 |A| a11 |A| x1 x2 . Therefore, for a linear mapping with |A| = 0, an 1-1 inverse mapping exists and the partial derivatives are given by the inverse matrix of A. For example, ∂x1 /∂y1 = a11 where∂y1 /∂x1 = a22 etc. The idea can be generalized to nonlinear mappings. |A| y1 x1 . . A general nonlinear mapping from Rn to Rn , y = . → x = . , is . . yn xn represented by a vector function x1 f 1 (y1 , . . . , yn ) . . . x= . = ≡ F (y). . . n xn f (y1 , . . . , yn ) 30 ∂x1 ∂x1 ... ∂y1 ∂yn . . .. . . . . . ∂xn ∂xn ... ∂y1 ∂yn Jacobian: Jacobian matrix: JF (y) ≡ ∂(x1 , . . . , xn ) ≡ |JF (y)|. ∂(y1 , . . . , yn ) = 1 1 f1 . . . fn . .. . . . . . . . n n f1 . . . fn Inverse function theorem: If x∗ = F (y ∗ ) and |JF (y ∗ )| = 0 (JF (y ∗ ) is non-singular), then F (y) is invertible nearby x∗ , g 1(x1 , . . . , xn ) . . that is, there exists a function G(x) ≡ such that y = G(x) if . n g (x1 , . . . , xn ) ∗ ∗ −1 x = F (y). In that case, JG (x ) = (JF (y )) . Reasoning: 1 1 dx1 f1 . . . fn dy1 . . .. . . . . = . . . . ⇒ . . . n n dxn f1 . . . fn dyn −1 1 1 1 1 dy1 g1 . . . gn dx1 f1 . . . fn dx1 . . .. . . . . . . . . = . . . . = . . . . . . . . . . . n n n n dyn g1 . . . gn dxn f1 . . . fn dxn Example: x2 and x1 JG = (JF )−1 . When r = 0, J = 0 and the mapping is degenerate, i.e., the whole set {r = 0, −π ≤ θ < π} is mapped to the origin (0, 0), just like the case in Lecture 3 when the Null space is a line. J = |JF | = r(cos2 θ + sin2 θ) = r > 0, ⇒ r = x2 + x2 , θ = tan−1 1 2 1 1 Notice that g1 = 1/(f1 ) in general. x1 x2 = F (r, θ) = r cos θ r sin θ . JF (r, θ) = cos θ −r sin θ sin θ r cos θ . 5.8 Implicit function theorem and comparative statics If |A| = 0, then the solution is given by x = −A−1 (By + c). The derivative matrix [∂xi /∂yj ]ij = A−1 B. Using total differentials of the equations, we can derive a similar derivative matrix for general nonlinear cases. Linear model: If all the equations are linear, the model can be represtned in matrix form as a11 · · · a1n x1 b11 · · · b1m y1 c1 0 . . . − . = . . . . . . . . . . Ax+By = c ⇔ . . . . . . + . . . . . . . . . . . an1 · · · ann xn bn1 · · · anm ym cn 0 31 We can regard the LHS of a nonlinear economic model as a mapping from Rn+m to Rn : f1 (x1 , . . . , xn ; y1 , . . . , ym ) = 0 . . ⇔ F (x; y) = 0. . fn (x1 , . . . , xn ; y1, . . . , ym ) = 0 1 1 f1 . . . fn . . Jacobian matrix: Jx ≡ . . . . . . . . n n f1 . . . fn Implicit function theorem: If F (x∗ ; y ∗) = 0 and |Jx (x∗ ; y ∗ )| = 0 (Jx (x∗ ; y ∗) is non-singular), then F (x; y) = 0 is solvable nearby (x∗ ; y ∗), that is, there exists a x1 x1 (y1 , . . . , ym ) . . . function x = . = x(y) = such that x∗ = x(y ∗ ) and . . xn xn (y1 , . . . , ym ) F (x(y); y) = 0. In that case, 1 1 ∂x1 ∂x1 −1 ∂f . . . ∂f ... 1 1 ∂y1 ∂y1 f1 . . . fn ∂ym ∂ym . . = − . . . . . . . .. .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ∂f n ∂xn n n ∂xn ∂f n f1 . . . fn ... ... ∂y1 ∂ym ∂y1 ∂ym Reasoning: ∂f 1 ∂f 1 1 1 ∂y1 . . . ∂ym dy1 df 1 0 f1 . . . fn dx1 . . . . . . . . . = 0 .. . . . = . ⇒ . . . . . . + . . . . . . . . . ∂f n n n ∂f n dym df n 0 f1 . . . fn dxn ... ∂y1 ∂ym 1 1 −1 ∂f . . . ∂f 1 1 ∂y1 dx1 f1 . . . fn ∂ym dy1 . . . . . .. . . . . ⇒ . = − . . . . . . . . . . . . . n n ∂f n n ∂f dxn f1 . . . fn dym ... ∂y1 ∂ym 1 2 2 Example: f = x1 x2 − y = 0, f = 2x1 − x2 − 1 = 0, When y = 1, (x1 , x2 ) = (1, 1) dx1 dx2 is an equilibrium. To calculate and at the equilibrium we use the implicit dy dy function theorem: dx1 ∂f 1 −1 1 1 ∂y f1 f2 dy dx = − 2 2 ∂f 2 2 f1 f2 dy ∂y = − 2x1 x2 x2 1 2 −1 −1 −1 0 =− 2 1 2 −1 −1 −1 0 = 1/4 1/2 . 32 5.9 Problems 1. Given the demand function Qd = (100/P ) − 10, find the demand elasticity η. 2 2 2 2. Given Y = X1 X2 + 2X1 X2 , find ∂Y /∂X1 , ∂ 2 Y /∂X1 , and ∂ 2 Y /∂X1 ∂X2 , and the total differential DY . 2 3. Given Y = F (X1 , X2 )+f (X1 )+g(X2), find ∂Y /∂X1 , ∂ 2 Y /∂X1 , and ∂ 2 Y /∂X1 ∂X2 . 4. Given the consumption function C = C(Y − T (Y )), find dC/dY . 5. Given that Q = D(q ∗ e/P ), find dQ/dP . 2 6. Y = X1 X2 , Z = Y 2 + 2Y − 2, use chain rule to derive ∂Z/∂X1 and ∂Z/∂X2 . 7. Y1 = X1 + 2X2 , Y2 = 2X1 + X2 , and Z = Y1 Y2 , use chain rule to derive ∂Z/∂X1 and ∂Z/∂X2 . 2 2 8. Let U(X1 , X2 ) = X1 X2 + X1 X2 and X2 = 2X1 + 1, find the partial derivative ∂U/∂X1 and the total derivative dU/dX1 . 9. X 2 + Y 3 = 1, use implicit function rule to find dY /dX. 2 2 10. X1 + 2X2 + Y 2 = 1, use implicit function rule to derive ∂Y /∂X1 and ∂Y /∂X2 . 11. F (Y1 , Y2, X) = Y1 − Y2 + X − 1 = 0 and G(Y1 , Y2, X) = Y12 + Y22 + X 2 − 1 = 0. use implicit function theorem to derive dY1 /dX and dY2 /dX. 12. In a Cournot quantity competition duopoly model with heterogeneous products, the demand functions are given by Q1 = a − P1 − cP2 , Q2 = a − cP1 − P2 ; 1 ≥ c > 0. (a) For what value of c can we invert the demand functions to obtain P1 and P2 as functions of Q1 and Q2 ? (b) Calculate the inverse demand functions P1 = P1 (Q1 , Q2 ) and P2 = P2 (Q1 , Q2 ). (c) Derive the total revenue functions T R1 (Q1 , Q2 ) = P1 (Q1 , Q2 )Q1 and T R2 (Q1 , Q2 ) = P2 (Q1 , Q2 )Q2 . 13. In a 2-good market equilibrium model, the inverse demand functions are given by P1 = A1 Qα−1 Qβ , P2 = A2 Qα Qβ−1 ; α, β > 0. 1 2 1 2 (a) Calculate the Jacobian matrix ∂(P1 , P2 ) ∂P1 /∂Q1 ∂P1 /∂Q2 and Jacobian . ∂P2 /∂Q1 ∂P2 /∂Q2 ∂(Q1 , Q2 ) What condition(s) should the parameters satisfy so that we can invert the functions to obtain the demand functions? (b) Derive the Jacobian matrix of the derivatives of (Q1 , Q2 ) with respect to ∂Q1 /∂P1 ∂Q1 /∂P2 (P1 , P2 ), . ∂Q2 /∂P1 ∂Q2 /∂P2 33 5.10 Proofs of important theorems of differentiation Rolle’s theorem: If f (x) ∈ C[a, b], f ′ (x) exists for all x ∈ (a, b), and f (a) = f (b) = 0, then there exists a c ∈ (a, b) such that f ′ (c) = 0. Proof: Case 1: f (x) ≡ 0 ∀x ∈ [a, b] ⇒ f ′ (x) = 0 ∀x ∈ (a, b)./ Case 2: f (x) ≡ 0 ∈ [a, b] ⇒ ∃e, c such that f (e) = m ≤ f (x) ≤ M = f (c) and M > m. Assume that M = 0 (otherwise m = 0 and the proof is similar). It is easy ′ ′ to see that f− (c) ≥ 0 and f+ (c) ≤ 0. Therefore, f ′ (c) = 0. Q.E.D. Mean Value theorem: If f (x) ∈ C[a, b] and f ′ (x) exists for all x ∈ (a, b). Then there exists a c ∈ (a, b) such that f (b) − f (a) = f ′ (c)(b − a). Proof: Consider the function φ(x) ≡ f (x) − f (a) + f (b) − f (a) (x − a) . b−a It is clear that φ(x) ∈ C[a, b] and φ′ (x) exists for all x ∈ (a, b). Also, φ(a) = φ(b) = 0 so that the conditions of Rolle’s Theorem are satisfied for φ(x). Hence, there exists a c ∈ (a, b) such that φ′ (c) = 0, or φ′ (c) = f ′ (c) − f (b) − f (a) f (b) − f (a) = 0 ⇒ f ′ (c) = = 0. b−a b−a r (r+1) Taylor’s Theorem: If f (x) ∈ C [a, b] and f there exists a c ∈ (a, b) such that Q.E.D. (x) exists for all x ∈ (a, b). Then 1 1 1 f (r+1) (c)(b−a)r+1 . f (b) = f (a)+f ′ (a)(b−a)+ f ′′ (a)(b−a)2 +. . .+ f (r) (a)(b−a)r + 2 r! (r + 1)! Proof: Define ξ ∈ R (b − a)r+1 1 1 ξ ≡ f (b)− f (a) + f ′ (a)(b − a) + f ′′ (a)(b − a)2 + . . . + f (r) (a)(b − a)r . (r + 1)! 2 r! Consider the function 1 φ(x) ≡ f (b) − f (x) + f ′ (x)(b − x) + f ′′ (x)(b − x)2 + . . . + 2 1 (r) ξ f (x)(b − x)r + (b − x)r+1 . r! (r + 1)! 34 It is clear that φ(x) ∈ C[a, b] and φ′ (x) exists for all x ∈ (a, b). Also, φ(a) = φ(b) = 0 so that the conditions of Rolle’s Theorem are satisfied for φ(x). Hence, there exists a c ∈ (a, b) such that φ′ (c) = 0, or φ′ (c) = ξ − f (r+1) (c) = 0 ⇒ f (r+1) (c) = ξ. r! n Q.E.D. Inverse Function Theorem: Let E ⊆ R be an open set. Suppose f : E → Rn is C 1 (E), a ∈ E, f (a) = b, and A = J(f (a)), |A| = 0. Then there exist open sets U, V ⊂ Rn such that a ∈ U, b ∈ V , f is one to one on U, f (U) = V , and f −1 : V → U is C 1 (U). Proof: (1. Find U.) Choose λ ≡ |A|/2. Since f ∈ C 1 (E), there exists a neighborhood U ⊆ E with a ∈ U such that J(f (x)) − A < λ. (2. Show that f (x) is one to one in U.) For each y ∈ Rn define φy on E by φy (x) ≡ x + A−1 (y − f (x)). Notice that f (x) = y if and only if x is a fixed point of 1 φy . Since J(φy (x)) = I − A−1 J(f (x)) = A−1 [A − J(f (x))] ⇒ J(φy (x)) < on U. 2 Therefore φy (x) is a contraction mapping and there exists at most one fixed point in U. Therefore, f is one to one in U. (3. V = f (U) is open so that f −1 is continuous.) Let V = f (U) and y0 = f (x0 ) ∈ V for x0 ∈ U. Choose an open ball B about x0 with radius ρ such that the closure [B] ⊆ U. To prove that V is open, it is enough to show that y ∈ V whenever y − y0 < λρ. So fix y such that y − y0 < λρ. With φy defined above, ρ φy (x0 ) − x0 = A−1 (y − y0 ) < A−1 λρ = . 2 If x ∈ [B] ⊆ U, then φy (x) − x0 ≤ φy (x) − φy (x0 ) + φy (x0 ) − x0 < 1 ρ x − x0 + ≤ ρ. 2 2 That is, φy (x) ∈ [B]. Thus, φy (x) is a contraction of the complete space [B] into itself. Hence, φy (x) has a unique fixed point x ∈ [B] and y = f (x) ∈ f ([B]) ⊂ f (U) = V . (4. f −1 ∈ C −1 .) Choose y1 , y2 ∈ V , there exist x1 , x2 ∈ U such that f (x1 ) = y1 , f (x2 ) = y2 . φy (x2 ) − φy (x1 ) = x2 − x1 + A−1 (f (x1 ) − f (x2 )) = (x2 − x1 ) − A−1 (y2 − y1 ). ⇒ (x2 −x1 )−A−1 (y2 −y1 ) ≤ or x2 − x1 ≤ 1 1 1 x2 −x1 ⇒ x2 −x1 ≤ A−1 (y2 −y1 ) ≤ y2 −y1 2 2 2λ 1 y2 − y1 . It follows that (f ′ )−1 exists locally about a. Since λ f −1 (y2 ) − f −1 (y1 ) − (f ′ )−1 (y1 )(y2 − y1 ) = (x2 − x1 ) − (f ′ )−1 (y1 )(y2 − y1 ) = −(f ′ )−1 (y1 )[−f ′ (x1 )(x2 − x1 ) + f (x2 ) − f (x1 )], 35 We have f −1 (y2 ) − f −1 (y1) − (f ′ )−1 (y1 )(y2 − y1 ) (f ′ )−1 ≤ y2 − y1 λ f (x2 ) − f (x1 ) − f ′ (x1 )(x2 − x1 ) . x2 − x1 As y2 →y1 , x2 →x1 . Hence (f 1− )′ (y) = {f ′[f −1 (y)]} for y ∈ V . Since f −1 is differentiable, it is continuous. Also, f ′ is continuous and its inversion, where it exists, is continuous. Therefore (f −1 )′ is continuous or f −1 ∈ C 1 (V ). Q.E.D. Implicit Function Theorem: Let E ⊆ R(n+m) be an open set and a ∈ Rn , b ∈ Rm , (a, b) ∈ E. Suppose f : E → Rn is C 1 (E) and f (a, b) = 0, and J(f (a, b)) = 0. Then there exist open sets A ⊂ Rn and B ⊂ Rm a ∈ A and b ∈ B, such that for each x ∈ B, there exists a unique g(x) ∈ A such that f (g(x), x) = 0 and g : B → A is C 1 (B). Proof: Defining F : Rn+m →Rn+m by F (x, y) ≡ (x, f (x, y)). Note that since J(F (a, b)) = ∂xi ∂xj 1≤i,j≤n ∂fi ∂xj 1≤i≤m,1≤j≤n ∂xi ∂xn+j 1≤i≤n,1≤j≤m = ∂fi ∂xn+j 1≤i,j≤m I O N M , |J(F (a, b))| = |M| = 0. By the Inverse Function Theorem there exists an open set V ⊆ Rn+m containing F (a, b) = (a, 0) and an open set of the form A × B ⊆ E containing (a, b), such that F : A × B→V has a C 1 inverse F −1 : V →A × B. F −1 is of the form F −1 (x, y) = (x, φ(x, y)) for some C 1 function φ. Define the projection π : Rn+m →Rm by π(x, y) = y. Then π ◦ F (x, y) = f (x, y). Therefore f (x, φ(x, y)) = f ◦ F −1 (x, y) = (π ◦ F ) ◦ F −1 (x, y) = π ◦ (F ◦ F −1 )(x, y) = π(x, y) = y and f (x, φ(x, 0)) = 0. So, define g : A→B by g(x) = φ(x, 0). Q.E.D. 36 6 6.1 Comparative Statics – Economic applications Partial equilibrium model Q = D(P, Y ) Q = S(P ) ∂D ∂D < 0, >0 ∂P ∂Y ′ S (P ) > 0 end. var: Q, P. ex. var: Y.. f 1 (P, Q; Y ) = Q − D(P, Y ) = 0 f 2 (P, Q; Y ) = Q − S(P ) = 0 dQ ∂D ∂D dY 1 − , |J| = dP = ∂P ∂Y 1 −S ′ (P ) 0 dY ∂D ∂D − ∂D ′ ∂Y ∂P S (P ) − 0 −S ′ (P ) dQ = = ∂Y > 0, dY |J| |J| 6.2 Income determination model C = C(Y ) I = I(r) ¯ Y =C +I +G dQ ∂D dP ∂D df 1 = − − =0 dY2 dY ∂P dY ∂Y . df dQ dP = − S ′ (P ) =0 dY dY dY ∂D ∂P 1 −S ′ (P ) 1 − 1 dP = dY = −S ′ (P ) + ∂D < 0. ∂P ∂D ∂Y 1 0 |J| ∂D = ∂Y > 0. |J| − 0 < C ′ (Y ) < 1. I ′ (r) < 0 end. var. C, Y, I ¯ ex. var. G, r. ¯ I ′ (r)dr + dG ¯ ¯ Y = C(Y ) + I(r) + G ⇒ dY = C ′ (Y )dY + I ′ (r)dr + dG ⇒ dY = . 1 − C ′ (Y ) ∂Y I ′ (r) ∂Y 1 = < 0, ′ (Y ) ¯ = 1 − C ′ (Y ) > 0. ∂r 1−C ∂G 6.2.1 Income determination and trade Consider an income determination model with import and export: C = C(Y ) 1 > Cy > 0, M = M(Y, e) My > 0, Me < 0 C + I + X − M = Y, ¯ I = I, X = X(Y ∗ , e), Xy∗ > 0, Xe > 0 where import M is a function of domestic income and exchange rate e and export X is a function of exchange rate and foreign income Y ∗ , both are assumed here as exogenous variables. Substituting consumption, import, and export functions into the equilibrium condition, we have ¯ C(Y )+I+X(Y ∗ , e)−M(Y, e) = Y, ¯ ⇒F (Y, e, Y ∗ ) ≡ C(Y )+I+X(Y ∗ , e)−M(Y, e)−Y = 0.. 37 Use implicit function rule to derive ∂Y ¯ and determine its sign: ∂I 1 ∂Y FI =− = . ¯ Fy 1 − C ′ (Y ) + My ∂I Use implicit function rule to derive ∂Y and determine its sign: ∂e Fe Xe − Me ∂Y =− = . ∂e Fy 1 − C ′ (Y ) + My Use implicit function rule to derive ∂Y and determine its sign: ∂Y ∗ Fy∗ Xy ∗ ∂Y =− = . ∗ ′ (Y ) + M ∂Y Fy 1−C y 6.2.2 Interdependence of domestic and foreign income Now extend the above income determination model to analyze the joint dependence of domestic income and foreign income: ¯ C(Y ) + I + X(Y ∗ , e) − M(Y, e) = Y ¯ C ∗ (Y ∗ ) + I ∗ + X ∗ (Y, e) − M ∗ (Y ∗ , e) = Y ∗ , ∗ with a similar assumption on the foreigner’s consumption function: 1 > Cy∗ > 0. Since domestic import is the same as foreigner’s export and domestic export is foreigner’s import, X ∗ (Y, e) = M(Y, e) and M ∗ (Y ∗ , e) = X(Y ∗ , e) and the system becomes: ¯ C(Y ) + I + X(Y ∗ , e) − M(Y, e) = Y ¯ C ∗ (Y ∗ ) + I ∗ + M(Y, e) − X(Y ∗ , e) = Y ∗ , ¯ (Xe − Me )de + dI ¯ (Me − Xe )de + dI ∗ Calculate the total differential of the system (Now Y ∗ becomes endogenous): 1 − C ′ + My −Xy∗ −My 1 − C ∗ ′ + Xy∗ |J| = 1 − C ′ + My −Xy∗ −My 1 − C ∗ ′ + Xy∗ dY dY ∗ = , = (1 − C ′ + My )(1 − C ∗ ′ + My∗ ) − My Xy∗ > 0. Use Cramer’s rule to derive ∂Y ∂Y ∗ and and determine their signs: ∂e ∂e dY = ¯ (Xe − Me )de + dI −Xy∗ ¯∗ 1 − C ∗ ′ + Xy∗ (Me − Xe )de + dI |J| ¯ ¯ (Xe − Me )(1 − C ∗ ′ + Xy∗ − Xy∗ )de + (1 − C ∗ ′ + Xy∗ )dI + Xy∗ dI ∗ = , |J| 38 ¯ 1 − C ′ + My (Xe − Me )de + dI ¯∗ (Me − Xe )de + dI −My |J| dY ∗ = = Derive ∂Y ∗ ∂Y and ¯ and determine their signs: ¯ ∂I ∂I ∂Y (Xe − Me )(1 − C ∗ ′ ) = > 0, ∂e |J| ¯ ¯ −(Xe − Me )(1 − C ′ + My − My )de + (1 − C ′ + My )dI ∗ + Xy dI . |J| ∂Y ∗ −(Xe − Me )(1 − C ′ ) = < 0. ∂e |J| ∂Y ∗ ∂Y 1 − C ∗ ′ + My∗ My =− > 0, ¯ ¯ = |J| < 0. |J| ∂I ∂I 6.3 IS-LM model C = C(Y ) 0 < C ′ (Y ) < 1 ∂L ∂L M d = L(Y, r) > 0, 0, = > 0, ¯ ¯ |J| |J| ∂G ∂M 6.4 ¯ ¯ Lr dG + I ′ dM , dr = |J| ∂r LY ∂r (1 − C ′ ) =− > 0, = < 0. ¯ ¯ |J| |J| ∂G ∂M ¯ 1 − C ′ dG ¯ LY dM |J| = Two-market general equilibrium model 1 2 2 Q1d = D 1 (P1 , P2 ) D1 < 0, Q2d = D 2 (P1 , P2 ) D2 < 0, D1 > 0. ′ ¯ Q2s = S2 (P2 ) S2 (P2 ) > 0 Q1s = S1 Q1d = Q1s Q2d = Q2s end. var: Q1 , Q2 , P1 , P2 . ¯ ex. var: S1 . ⇒ 1 1 ¯ D1 dP1 + D2 dP2 = dS1 2 2 ′ D1 dP1 + D2 dP2 − S2 dP2 = 0. ¯ D 1 (P1 , P2 ) = S1 2 D (P1 , P2 ) − S2 (P2 ) = 0 39 1 1 D1 D2 2 2 ′ D1 D2 − S 2 dP1 dP2 = ¯ d S1 0 , |J| = 1 1 2 2 Assumption: |D1 | > |D2 | and |D2 | > |D1 | (own-effects dominate), ⇒ |J| > 0. ′ 2 dP1 dP2 D 2 − S2 −D1 = 2 < 0, = 0, where Qn is the quantity of new cars and Pn (Pu ) the price of a new (used) car. The supply function of new cars is Qn = S(Pn ), S ′ (Pn ) > 0. end. var: Pn , Qn . n ex. var: Pu . ∂D n ∂D n dPn + dPu = S ′ (Pn )dPn . ⇒ ∂Pn ∂Pu D (Pn ; Pu ) = S(Pn ); dPn ∂D n /∂Pu dQn dPn S ′ (Pn )∂D n /∂Pu = ′ > 0, = S ′ (Pn ) = ′ > 0. dPu S (Pn ) − ∂D n /∂Pn dPu dPu S (Pn ) − ∂D n /∂Pn The markets for used cars and for new cars are actually interrelated. The demand for used cars is Qu = D u (Pu , Pn ), ∂D n /∂Pu < 0, ∂D n /∂Pn > 0. In each period, ¯ the quantity of used cars supplied is fixed, denoted by Qu . Instead of analyzing the effects of a change in Pu on the new car market, we want to know how a change in ¯ Qu affects both markets. end. var: Pn , Qn , Pu , Qu . Qn = D n (Pn , Pu ), ⇒ D n (Pn , Pu ) = S(Pn ), n n Dn − S ′ Du u u Dn Du ¯ ex. var: Qu . Qn = S(Pn ); ¯ D u (Pu , Pn ) = Qu ; = 0 ¯ dQu , |J| = Qu = D u (Pu , Pn ), n n Dn − S ′ Du u u Dn Du ¯ Qu = Qu n n Dn dPn +Du dPu = S ′ dPn , u u ¯ Dn dPn +Du dPu = Q dPn dPu n u n u = (Dn −S ′ )Du −Du Dn . n n u u Assumption: |Dn | > |Du | and |Du | > |Dn | (own-effects dominate), ⇒ |J| > 0. n dPn −Du dPu Dn − S ′ = < 0, = n < 0. ¯ ¯ |J| |J| dQu dQu ∂Qn ∂Qn ¯ ∂Qu From Qu = Qu , ¯ = 1. To calculate ¯ , we have to use chain rule: ¯ = ∂ Qu ∂ Qu ∂ Qu dPn S ′ ¯ < 0. dQn 40 6.5 Classic labor market model L = h(w) h′ > 0 labor supply function ∂Q w = MPPL = = FL (K, L) FLK > 0, FLL < 0 labor demand function. ∂L endogenous variables: L, w. exogenous variable: K. L − h(w) = 0 w − FL = 0 1 −h′ (w) −FLL 1 0 dL = dK 6.6 FLK dL dw −h′ (w) 1 |J| = ′ ⇒ dL − h′ (w)dw = 0 . dw − FLL dL − FLK dK = 0 , |J| = 1 −h′ (w) −FLL 1 = = 1−h′ (w)FLL > 0. FLK > 0. |J| 0 FLK dK = h FLK dw > 0, = |J| dK 1 0 −FLL FLK |J| Problem Q = D(P ) D ′ (P ) < 0 Q = S(P, t) ∂S/∂P > 0, ∂S/∂t < 0, where t is the tax rate on the commodity. (a) Derive the total differentail of each equation. (b) Use Cramer’s rule to compute dQ/dt and dP/dt. (c) Determine the sign of dQ/dt and dP/dt. (d) Use the Q − P diagram to explain your results. 1. Let the demand and supply functions for a commodity be 2. Suppose consumption C depends on total wealth W , well as on income Y . The IS-LM model becomes C = C(Y, W ) 0 < CY < 1 CW > 0 I = I(r) I ′ (r) < 0 M D = L(Y, r) LY > 0 Lr < 0 which is predetermind, as MS = M Y =C +I MS = MD (a) Which variables are endogenous? Which are exogenous? (b) Which equations are behavioral/institutional, which are equilibrium conditions? The model can be reduced to Y − C(Y, W ) − I(r) = 0, L(Y, r) = M. (c) Derive the total differential for each of the two equations. (d) Use Cramer’s rule to derive the effects of an increase in W on Y and r, ie., derive ∂Y /∂W and ∂r/∂W . (e) Determine the signs of ∂Y /∂W and ∂r/∂W . 41 3. Consider a 2-industry (e.g. manufacturing and agriculture) general equilibrium model. The demand for manufacturing product consists of two components: private demand D 1 and goverment demand G. The agricultural products have only private demand D 2 . Both D 1 and D 2 depend only on their own prices. Because each industry requires in its production process outputs of the other, the supply of each commodity depends on the price of the other commodity as well as on its own price. Therefore, the model may be written as follows: Qd 1 Qd 2 Qs 1 Qs 2 Qd 1 Qd 2 = = = = = = D1 (P1 ) + G D2 (P2 ) S 1 (P1 , P2 ) S 2 (P1 , P2 ) Qs , 1 Qs . 2 ′ D1 (P1 ) < 0, ′ D2 (P2 ) < 0, 1 1 1 1 S1 > 0, S2 < 0, S1 > |S2 |, 2 2 2 2 S1 < 0, S2 > 0, S2 > |S1 |, (a) Which variables are endogenous? Which are exogenous? (b) Which equations are behavioral? Which are definitional? Which are equilibrium conditions? 4. The model can be reduced to S 1 (P1 , P2 ) = D1 (P1 ) + G S 2 (P1 , P2 ) = D2 (P2 ) (c) Compute the total differential of each equation. (d) Use Cramer’s rule to derive ∂P1 /∂G and ∂P2 /∂G. (e) Determine the signs of ∂P1 /∂G and ∂P2 /∂G. (f) Compute ∂Q1 /∂G and ∂Q2 /∂G. (Hint: Use chain rule.) (g) Give an economic interpretation of the results. 5. The demand functions of a 2-commodity market model are: Qd = D 1 (P1 , P2 ) 1 Qd = D 2 (P1 , P2 ). 2 The supply of the first commodity is given exogenously, ie., Qs = S1 . The 1 supply of the second commodity depends on its own price, Qs = S2 (P2 ). The 2 equilibrium conditions are: Qd = Qs , 1 1 Qd = Qs . 2 2 (a) Which variables are endogenous? Which are exogenous? (b) Which equations are behavioral? Which are definitional? Which are equilibrium conditions? The model above can be reduced to : D 1 (P1 , P2 ) − S1 = 0 D 2 (P1 , P2 ) − S2 (P2 ) = 0 42 i Suppose that both commodities are not Giffen good (hence, Di < 0, i = 1, 2), i that each one is a gross substitute for the other (ie., Dj > 0, i = j), that i i ′ |Di | > |Dj |, and that S2 (P2 ) > 0. (c) Calculate the total differential of each equation of the reduced model. (d) Use Cramer’s rule to derive ∂P1 /∂S1 and ∂P2 /∂S1 . (e) Determine the signs of ∂P1 /∂S1 and ∂P2 /∂S1 . (f) Compute ∂Q1 /∂S1 and ∂Q2 /∂S1 and determine their signs. 6. The demand functions for fish and chicken are as follows: ′ Qd = DF (PF − PC ), DF < 0 F ′ Qd = DC (PC − PF ), DC < 0 C where PF , PC are price of fish and price of chicken respectively. The supply of fish depends on the number of fishermen (N) as well as its price PF : Qs = F F (PF , N), FPF > 0, FN > 0. The supply of chicken depends only on its price PC : Qs = C(PC ), C ′ > 0. The model can be reduced to C DF (PF − PC ) = F (PF , N) DC (PC − PF ) = C(PC ) (a) Find the total differential of the reduced system. (b) Use Cramer’s rule to find dPF /dN and dPC /dN. (c) Determine the signs of dPF /dN and dPC /dN. What is the economic meaning of your results? (d) Find dQC /dN. 7. In a 2-good market equilibrium model, the inverse demand functions are given by P1 = U1 (Q1 , Q2 ), P2 = U2 (Q1 , Q2 ); where U1 (Q1 , Q2 ) and U2 (Q1 , Q2 ) are the partial derivatives of a utility function U(Q1 , Q2 ) with respect to Q1 and Q2 , respectively. (a) Calculate the Jacobian matrix ∂(P1 , P2 ) ∂P1 /∂Q1 ∂P1 /∂Q2 and Jacobian . ∂P2 /∂Q1 ∂P2 /∂Q2 ∂(Q1 , Q2 ) What condition(s) should the parameters satisfy so that we can invert the functions to obtain the demand functions? (b) Derive the Jacobian matrix of the derivatives of (Q1 , Q2 ) with respect to ∂Q1 /∂P1 ∂Q1 /∂P2 (P1 , P2 ), . ∂Q2 /∂P1 ∂Q2 /∂P2 (c) Suppose that the supply functions are Q1 = a−1 P1 , Q2 = P2 , and Q∗ and Q∗ are market equilibrium quantities. Find the comparative 1 2 dQ∗ dQ∗ 1 2 statics and . (Hint: Eliminate P1 and P2 .) da da 43 8. In a 2-good market equilibrium model with a sales tax of t dollars per unit on product 1, the model becomes D 1 (P1 + t, P2 ) = Q1 = S1 (P1 ), D 2 (P1 + t, P2 ) = Q2 = S2 (P2 ). i i i Suppose that Di < 0 and Si′ > 0, |Di | > |Dj |, i = j, i, j = 1, 2. (a) Calculate dP2 /dt. (b) Calculate dQ2 /dt. i (c) Suppose that Dj > 0. Determine the signs of dP2 /dt and dQ2 /dt. i (d) Suppose that Dj < 0. Determine the signs of dP2 /dt and dQ2 /dt. (e) Explain your results in economics. 44 7 Optimization A behavioral equation is a summary of the decisions of a group of economic agents in a model. A demand (supply) function summarizes the consumption (production) decisions of consumers (producers) under different market prices, etc. The derivative of a behavioral function represents how agents react when an independent variable changes. In the last chapter, when doing comparative static analysis, we always assumed that the signs of derivatives of a behavioral equation in a model are known. For example, D ′ (P ) < 0 and S ′ (P ) > 0 in the partial market equilibrium model, C ′ (Y ) > 0, I ′ (r) < 0, Ly > 0, and Lr < 0 in the IS-LM model. In this chapter, we are going to provide a theoretical foundation for the determination of these signs. 7.1 Neoclassic methodology Neoclassic assumption: An agent, when making decisions, has an objective function in mind (or has well defined preferences). The agent will choose a feasible decision such that the objective function is maximized. A consumer will choose the quantity of each commodity within his/her budget constraints such that his/her utility function is maximized. A producer will choose to supply the quantity such that his profit is maximizaed. Remarks: (1) Biological behavior is an alternative assumption, sometimes more appropriate, (2) Sometimes an agent is actually a group of people with different personalities like a company and we have to use game theoretic equilibrium concepts to characterize the collective behavior. Maximization ⇒ Behavioral equations Game equilibrium ⇒ Equilibrium conditions x1 , . . . , xn : variables determined by the agent (endogenous variables). y1 , . . . , ym : variables given to the agent (exogenous variables). Objective function: f (x1 , . . . , xn ; y1 , . . . , ym). Opportunity set: the agent can choose only (x1 , . . . , xn ) such that (x1 , . . . , xn ; y1 , . . . , ym) ∈ A ⊂ Rn+m . A is usually defined by inequality constriants. g 1 (x1 , . . . , xn ; y1 , . . . , ym ) ≥ 0 . . max f (x1 , . . . , xn ; y1 , . . . , ym ) subject to . x1 ,...,xn k g (x , . . . , x ; y , . . . , y ) ≥ 0. 1 n 1 m Solution (behavioral equations): xi = xi (y1 , . . . , ym ), i = 1, . . . , n (derived from FOC). ∂xi /∂yj : derived by the comparative static method (sometimes its sign can be determined from SOC). Example 1: A consumer maximizes his utility function U(q1 , q2 ) subject to the budget constraint p1 q1 + p2 q2 = m ⇒ demand functions q1 = D 1 (p1 , p2 , m) and q2 = D 2 (p1 , p2 , m). 45 Example 2: A producer maximizes its profit Π(Q; P ) = P Q − C(Q) where C(Q) is the cost of producing Q units of output ⇒ the supply function Q = S(P ). one endogenous variable: this chapter. n endogenous variables without constraints: next n endogenous variables with equality constraints: Nonlinear programming: n endogenous variables with inequality constraints Linear programming: Linear objective function with linear inequality constraints Game theory: more than one agents with different objective functions 7.2 Different concepts of maximization Suppose that a producer has to choose a Q to maximize its profit π = F (Q): maxQ F (Q). Assume that F ′ (Q) and F ′′ (Q) exist. A local maximum Ql : there exists ǫ > 0 such that F (Ql ) ≥ F (Q) for all Q ∈ (Ql − ǫ, Ql + ǫ). A global maximum Qg : F (Qg ) ≥ F (Q) for all Q. A unique global maximum Qu : F (Qu ) > F (Q) for all Q = Qu . F F F T l : local max. Q T T Qg : a global max. Qu : unique global max not global max but not unique Ql EQ Qg EQ Qu EQ The agent will choose only a global maximum as the quantity supplied to the market. However, it is possible that there are more than one global maximum. In that case, the supply quantity is not unique. Therefore, we prefer that the maximization problem has a unique global maximum. A unique global maximum must be a global maximum and a global maximum must be a local maximum. ⇒ to find a global maximum, we first find all the local maxima. One of them must be a global maximum, otherwise the problem does not have a solution (the maximum occurs at ∞.) We will find conditions (eg., increasing MC or decreasing MRS) so that there is only one local maximum which is also the unique global maximum. 7.3 FOC and SOC for a local maximum At a local maximum Ql , the slope of the graph of F (Q) must be horizontal F ′ (Ql ) = 0. This is called the first order condition (FOC) for a local maximum. A critical point Qc : F ′ (Qc ) = 0. A local maximum must be a critical point but a critical point does not have to be a local maximum. 46 F F F T F ′′ (Qc ) < 0 local max. T T F ′′ (Qc ) = 0 degenerate F ′′ (Qc ) > 0 local min. Qc EQ Qc EQ Qc EQ A degenerate critical point: F ′ (Q) = F ′′ (Q) = 0. A non-degenerate critical point: F ′ (Q) = 0, F ′′ (Q) = 0. A non-degenerate critical point is a local maximum (minimum) if F ′′ (Q) < 0 (F ′′ (Q) > 0). FOC: F ′ (Ql ) = 0 SOC: F ′′ (Ql ) < 0 Example: F (Q) = −15Q + 9Q2 − Q3 , F ′ (Q) = −15 + 18Q − 3Q2 = −3(Q − 1)(Q − 5). There are two critical points: Q = 1, 5. F ′′ (Q) = 18 − 6Q, F ′′ (1) = 12 > 0, and F ′′ (5) = −12 < 0. Therefore, Q = 5 is a local maximum. It is a global maximum for 0 ≤ Q < ∞. Remark 1 (Degeneracy): For a degenerate critical point, we have to check higher order derivatives. If the lowest order non-zero derivative is of odd order, then it is a reflect point; eg., F (Q) = (Q − 5)3 , F ′ (5) = F ′′ (5) = 0 and F ′′′ (5) = 6 = 0 and Q = 5 is not a local maximum. If the lowest order non-zero derivative is of even order and negative (positive), then it is a local maximum (minimum); eg., F (Q) = −(Q − 5)4 , F ′ (5) = F ′′ (5) = F ′′′ (5) = 0, F (4) (5) = −24 < 0 and Q = 5 is a local maximum. Remark 2 (Unboundedness): If limQ→∞ F (Q) = ∞, then a global maximum does not exist. Remark 3 (Non-differentiability): If F (Q) is not differentiable, then we have to use other methods to find a global maximum. Remark 4 (Boundary or corner solution): When there is non-negative restriction Q ≥ 0 (or an upper limit Q ≤ a), it is possible that the solution occurs at Q = 0 (or at Q = a). To take care of such possibilities, FOC is modified to become F ′ (Q) ≤ 0, QF ′ (Q) = 0 (or F ′ (Q) ≥ 0, (a − Q)F ′ (Q) = 0). 7.4 Supply function of a competitive producer Consider first the profit maximization problem of a competitive producer: max Π = P Q − C(Q), Q FOC ⇒ ∂Π = P − C ′ (Q) = 0. ∂Q The FOC is the inverse supply function (a behavioral equation) of the producer: P = C ′ (Q) = MC. Remember that Q is endogenous and P is exogenous here. To find 47 dQ the comparative statics , we use the total differential method discussed in the last dP chapter: dQ 1 dP = C ′′ (Q)dQ, ⇒ = ′′ . dP C (Q) To determine the sign of fore, dQs > 0. dP dQ ∂2Π , we need the SOC, which is = −C ′′ (Q) < 0. TheredP ∂Q2 Remark: The result is true no matter what the cost function C(Q) is. MC = C ′ (Q) can be non-monotonic, but the supply curve is only part of the increasing sections of the MC curve and can be discontinuous. P T P MC MC is the supply curve. T MC Pc S(Pc ) = {Q1 , Q2 }, supply curve has two component. EQ Q1 Q2 EQ 7.5 Maximization and comparative statics: general procedure X Maximization problem of an agent: max F (X; Y ). FOC: FX (X ∗ ; Y ) = 0, ⇒ X ∗ = X(Y ) · · · · · · Behavioral Equation dX FXY Comparative statics: FXX dX + FXY dY = 0 ⇒ =− . SOC: FXX < 0 dY FXX dX FXY Case 1: FXY > 0 ⇒ =− > 0. dY FXX dX FXY Case 2: FXY < 0 ⇒ =− < 0. dY FXX dX Therefore, the sign of depends only on the sign of FXY . dY 7.6 Utility Function A consumer wants to maximize his/her utility function U = u(Q) + M = u(Q) + (Y − P Q). ∂U FOC: = u′ (Q) − P = 0, ∂Q ⇒ u′ (Qd ) = P (inverse demand function) ⇒ Qd = D(P ) (demand function, a behavioral equation) 48 dQd ∂2U = UP Q = −1 ⇒ = D ′ (P ) < 0, the demand function is a decreasing ∂Q∂P dP function of price. 7.7 Input Demand Function The production function of a producer is given by Q = f (x), where x is the quantity of an input employed. Its profit is Π = pf (x) − wx, where p (w) is the price of the output (input). The FOC of profit maximization problem is pf ′ (x) − w = 0 ⇒ f ′ (x) = w/p (inverse input demand function) ⇒ x = h(w/p) (input demand function, a behavioral equation) ∂2Π dx = −1 ⇒ = h′ (w/p) < 0, the input demand is a decreasing func∂x∂(w/p) d(w/p) w tion of the real input price . p 7.8 Envelope theorem Define the maximum function M(Y ) ≡ maxX F (X, Y ) = F (X(Y ), Y ) then the total derivative dM ∂F (X, Y ) = M ′ (Y ) = . dY ∂Y X=X(Y ) dX Proof: M ′ (Y ) = FX + FY . At the maximization point X = X(Y ), FOC implies dY that the indirect effect of Y on M is zero. In the consumer utility maximization problem, V (P ) ≡ U(D(P )) + Y − P D(P ) is called the indirect utility function. The envelope theorem implies that V ′ (P ) = dU ≡ −D(P ), this is a simplified version of Roy’s identity. dP Qd =D(P ) In the input demand function problem, π(w, p) ≡ pf (h(w/p)) − wh(w/p) is the profit function. Let p = 1 and still write π(w) ≡ f (h(w)) − wh(w). The envelope theorem dΠ implies that π ′ (w) = = −h(w), a simplified version of Hotelling’s lemma. dw x=h(w) Example: The relationships between LR and SR cost curves STC(Q; K) = C(Q, K), K: firm size. Each K corresponds to a STC. LTC(Q) = minK C(Q, K), ⇒ K = K(Q) is the optimal firm size. LTC is the envelope of STC’s. Each STC tangents to the LTC (STC = LTC) at the quantity Q such that K = K(Q). Notice that the endogenous variable is K and the exogenous is Q here. By envelope theorem, LMC(Q) = dLTC(Q)/dQ = ∂C(Q, K(Q))/∂Q =SMC(Q; K(Q)). That is, when K = K(Q) is optimal for producing Q, SMC=LMC. 49 Since LAC(Q) =LTC(Q)/Q and SAC(Q) =STC(Q)/Q, LAC is the envelope of SAC’s and each SAC tangents to the LAC (SAC = LAC) at the quantity Q such that K = K(Q). 7.9 Effect of a Unit Tax on Monopoly Output (Samuelson) Assumptions: a monopoly firm, q = D(P ) ⇐⇒ P = f (q), (inverse functions), C = C(q), t = unit tax max π(q) = P q − C(q) − tq = qf (q) − C(q) − tq q: endogenous; t: exogenous FOC: ∂π/∂q = f (q) + qf ′ (q) − C ′ (q) − t = 0. The FOC defines a relationship between the monopoly output q ∗ and the tax rate t as q ∗ = q(t) (a behavioral equation). The derivative dq ∗ /dt can be determined by the sign of the cross derivative: ∂2π = −1 < 0 ∂q∂t Therefore, we have dq ∗ /dt < 0. The result can be obtained using the q–pdiagram. FOC ⇐⇒ MR = MC + t. Therefore, on q–p space, an equilibrium is determined by the intersection point of MR and MC + t curves. Case 1: MR is downward sloping and MC is upward sloping: When t increases, q ∗ decreases as seen from the left diagram below. P P T T MC+t MC MRE MC+t MC < q < MRE q Case 2: Both MR and MC are downward sloping and MR is steeper. MC decreasing; MR decreasing more ⇒ t ↑ q ↓. Case 3: Both MR and MC are downward sloping, but MC is steeper. The diagram shows that dq ∗ /dt > 0. It is opposite to our comparative statics result. Why? MR = MC + t violates SOC < 0, therefore, the intersection of MR and MC + t is not a profit maximizing point. 50 P T MR MC+t > 7.10 MCE q A Price taker vs a price setter A producer employs an input X to produce an output Q. The production function is Q = rX. The inverse demand function for Q is P = a − Q. The inverse supply function of X is W = b + X, where W is the price of X. The producer is the only seller of Q and only buyer of X. There are two markets, Q (output) and X (input). We want to find the 2-market equilibrium, i.e., the equilibrium values of W , X, Q, and P . It depends on the producer’s power in each market. Case 1: The firm is a monopolist in Q and a price taker in X. To the producer, P is endogenous and W is exogenous. Given W , its object is max π = P Q−W X = (a−Q)Q−W X = (a−rX)(rX)−W X, x ⇒ FOC ar−2r 2 X−W = 0. The input demand function is X = X(W ) = ar−W . 2r 2 ar−b Equating the demand and supply of X, the input market equilibrium is X = 2r2 +1 2b and W = b + X = ar+2r . 2r 2 +1 Substituting back into the production and output demand functions, the output market equilibrium is Q = rX = f ar 2 − br2r 2 + 1 and P = a − Q = f a + ar 2 + b2r 2 + 1. Case 2: The firm is a price taker in Q and a monopsony in X. To the producer, P is exogenous and W is endogenous. Given P , its object is b 2Q max π = P Q − (b + X)X = P Q − (b + (Q/r))(Q/r), ⇒ FOC P − − 2 = 0. Q r r The output supply function is Q = Q(P ) = r P2−br . 2 −br Equating the demand and supply of Q, the output market equilibrium is Q = ar2 −2 r 2a+br and P = a − Q = 2r2 +1 . Substituting back into the production and output demand functions, the output market equilibrium is X = Q/r = f ar − br 2 − 2 and W = b + X = f ar + br 2 − 3br 2 − 2. Case 3: The firm is a monopolist in Q and a monopsony in X. To the producer, both P and W are endogenous, its object is max π = (a − Q)Q − (b + X)X = (a − (rX))(rX) − (b + X)X. x 2 51 (We can also eliminate X instead of Q. The two procedures are the same.) (Show that π is strictly concave in X.) Find the profit maximizing X as a function of a and b, X = X(a, b). ∂X ∂X Determine the sign of the comparative statics and and explain your results ∂a ∂b in economics. Derive the price and the wage rate set by the firm P and W and compare the results with that of cases 1 and 2. 7.11 Labor Supply Function Consider a consumer/worker trying to maximize his utility function subject to the time constraint that he has only 168 hours a week to spend between work (N) and leisure (L), N + L = 168, and the budget constraint which equates his consumption (C) to his wage income (wN), C = wN, as follows: max U = U(C, L) = U(wN, 168 − N) ≡ f (N, w) Here N is endogenous and w is exogenous. The FOC requires that the total derivative of U w.r.t. N be equal to 0. FOC: dU = fN = UC w + UL (−1) = 0. dN FOC defines a relationship between the labor supply of the consumer/worker, N, and the wage rate w, which is exactly the labor supply function of the individual N ∗ = N(w). The slope the supply function N ′ (w) is determined by the sign of the cross-derivative fN w C ← N ւ U, Uc , UL ւ տ տ L w fN w = UC + wNUCC − NULC The sign of fN w is indeterminate, therefore, the slope of N ∗ = N(w) is also indeterminate. Numerical Examples: √ √ Example 1: U = 2 C + 2 L elasticity of substitution σ > 1 √ √ √ √ U = 2 C+2 L = 2 wN+2 168 − N , dU w 1 w 1 = √ −√ = √ −√ = 0. dN 168 − N C L wN 52 Therefore, the inverse labor supply function is w = N/(168 − N), which is positively sloped. w w T σ>1 T EN σ 0, then we define y ≡ loga x = . ln a 1 d Using inverse function rule: dx = ey dy, ln x = ln x = 1/x. dx e y y = ex T y = ln x Ex x ax = eln a = e(ln a)x ⇒ d lna x = dx 1 ln a 1 x d x a = (ln a)e(ln a)x = (ln a)ax . dx growth rate of a function of time y = f (t): growth rate ≡ 1 dy f′ d = = [ln f (t)]. y dt f dt Example: f (t) = g(t)h(t). ln f (t) = ln g(t) + ln h(t), therefore, growth rate of f (t) is equal to the sum of the growth rates of g(t) and h(t). Interest compounding A: principal (PV), V = Future Value, r = interest rate, n = number of periods V = A(1 + r)n If we compound interest m times per period, then the interest rate each time becomes r/m, the number of times of compounding becomes mn, and V = A[(1 + r/m)m ]n m→∞ lim (1 + r/m)m = 1 + r + r 2 /2! + · · · + r n /n! + . . . = er Therefore, V → Aern , this is the formula for instantaneous compounding. 54 7.13 Timing: (when to cut a tree) t: number √ years to wait, A(t) present value after t years of V (t) = Ke√ t : the market value of the tree after t years A(t) = Ke t e−rt is the present value We want to find the optimal t such that the present value is maximized. max A(t) = Ke t e−rt . t √ The FOC is A′ = Because A(t) = 0, FOC implies: 1 √ − r A(t) = 0 2 t 1 √ − r = 0, t∗ = 1/(4r 2) 2 t For example, if r = 10%, t = 25, then to wait 25 years before cutting the tree is the optimum. Suppose that A(t) = ef (t) FOC becomes: A′ (t)/A(t) = f ′ (t) = r, ⇒ f ′ (t) is the instantaneous growth rate (or the marginal growth rate) at t, ⇒ at t = 25, growth rate = 10% = r, at t = 26, growth rate < 10%. Therefore, it is better to cut and sell the tree at t = 25 and put the proceed in the bank than waiting longer. SOC: It can be shown that A′′ < 0. 7.14 Problems 1. Suppose the total cost function of a competitive firm is C(Q) = eaQ+b . Derive the supply function. 2. The input demand function of a competitive producer, X = X(W ), can be derived by maximizing the profit function Π = F (X) − W X with respect to X, where X is the quantity of input X and W is the price of X. Derive the comparative statics dX/dW and determine its sign. 3. The utility function of a consumer is given by U = U(X) + M, where X is the quantity of commodity X consumed and M is money. Suppose that the total income of the consumer is $ 100 and that the price of X is P . Then the utility function become U(X) + (100 − XP ). (a) Find the first order condition of the utility maximization problem. (b) What is the behavior equation implied by the first order condition? (c) Derive dX/dP and determine its sign. What is the economic meaning of your result? 4. The consumption function of a consumer, C = C(Y ), can be derived by maximizing the utility function U(C, Y ) = u1 (C) + u2 (Y − C), where u′1 (C) > 0, u′2 (Y − C) > 0 and u1 ”(C) < 0, u2 ”(Y − C) < 0. Derive the comparative statics dC/dY and determine its sign. 55 5. Consider a duopoly market with two firms, A and B. The inverse demand function is P = f (QA + QB ), f ′ < 0, f ” < 0. The cost function of firm A is T CA = C(QA ), C ′ > 0, C” > 0. The profit of firm A is ΠA = P QA − T CA = QA f (QA + QB ) − C(QA ). For a given output of firm B, QB , there is a QA which maximizes firm A’s profit. This relationship between QB and QA is called the reaction function of firm A, QA = RA (QB ). ′ (a) Find the slope of the reaction function RA = dQA . dQB (b) When QB increases, will firm A’s output QA increase or decrease? 6. The profit of a monopolistic firm is given by Π = R(x) − C(x, b), where x is output, b is the price of oil, R(x) is total revenue, and C(x, b) is the total cost function. For any given oil price b, there is an optimal output which maximizes profit, that is, the optimal output is a function of oil price, x = x(b). Assume that Cbx = ∂ 2 C/∂b∂x > 0, that is, an increase in oil price will increase marginal cost. Will an increase in oil price increase output, that is, is dx/db > 0? 7. Consider a monopsony who uses a single input, labor (L), for the production of a commodity (Q), which he sells in a perfect competition market. His production function is Q = F (L), (f ′ (L) > 0). The labor supply function is L = L(w), or more convenient for this problem, w = L−1 (L) = W (L). Given the commodity price p, there is an optimal labor input which maximizes the monopsonist’s total profit Π = pf (L) − W (L)L. In this problem, you are asked to derive the relation between L and p. (a) State the FOC and the SOC of the profit maximization problem. (b) Derive the comparative statics dL/dp and determine its sign. 8. Suppose that a union has a fixed supply of labor (L) to sell, that unemployed workers are paid unemployment insurance at a rate of $u per worker, and that the union wishes to maximize the sum of the wage bill plus the unemployment compensation S = wD(w) + u(L − D(w)), where w is wage per worker, D(w) is labor demand function, and D ′ (w) < 0. Show that if u increases, then the union should set a higher w. (Hint: w is endogenous and u is exogenous.) 9. The production function of a competitive firm is given by Q = F (L, K). where L is variable input and K is fixed input. The short run profit function is given by Π = pQ−wL−rK, where p is output price, w is wage rate, and r is the rental rate on capital. In the short run, given the quantity of fixed input K,there is a L which maximizes Π. Hence, the short run demand for L can be regarded as a function of K. Assume that FLK > 0. (a) State the FOC and SOC of the profit maximization problem. (b) Derive the comparative statics dL/dK and determine its sign. 56 7.15 Concavity and Convexity The derivation of a behavioral equation X = X(Y ) from the maximization problem maxx F (X; Y ) is valid only if there exists a unique global maximum for every Y . If there are multiple global maximum, then X = X(Y ) has multiple values and the comparative static analysis is not valid. Here we are going to discuss a condition on F (X; Y ) so that a critical point is always a unique global maximum and the comparative static analysis is always valid. Convex sets A is a convex set if ∀X 0 , X 1 ∈ A and 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1, X θ ≡ (1 − θ)X 0 + θX 1 ∈ A. (If X 0 , X 1 ∈ A then the whole line connecting X 0 and X 1 is in A.) x2 x2 T 1( 0) d d T 52 43 E x1 some non-convex sets some convex sets E x1 (1) If A1 and A2 are convex, then A1 ∩ A2 is convex but A1 ∪ A2 is not necessarily convex. Also, the empty set itself is a convex set. (2) The convex hull of A is the smallest convex set that contains A. For example, the convex hull of {X 0 } ∪ {X 1 } is the straight line connecting X 0 and X 1 . Convex and concave functions Given a function F (X), we define the sets G+ ≡ {(x, y)| y ≥ F (x), x ∈ R}, F G− ≡ {(x, y)| y ≤ F (x), x ∈ R}, F − G+ , GF ⊂ R 2 . F If G+ (G− ) is a convex set, then we say F (X) is a convex function (a concave funcF F tion). If F (X) is defined only for nonnegative values X ≥ 0, the definition is similar. T T G+ F F (X) + GF F (X) G− F EX G− F EX G− is a convex set ⇒ F (X) is concave F G+ is a convex set ⇒ F (X) is convex F Equivalent Definition: Given X 0 < X 1 , 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1, denote F 0 = F (X 0 ), F 1 = F (X 1 ). Define X θ ≡ (1 − θ)X 0 + θX 1 , F (X θ ) = F ((1 − θ)X 0 + θX 1 ). Also 57 define F θ ≡ (1 − θ)F (X 0 ) + θF (X 1 ) = (1 − θ)F 0 + θF 1 . F 1 = F (X 1 ) T F (X θ ) F (X) Fθ F0 F1 T F 0 = F (X 0 ) X 0 X θ X 1 EX X 0 X θ X 1 EX Therefore, (X θ , F θ ) is located on the straight line connecting (X 0 , F 0 ) and (X 1 , F 1 ) and when θ shifts from 0 to 1, (X θ , F θ ) shifts from (X 0 , F 0 ) to (X 1 , F 1 ) (the right figure). On the other hand, (X θ , F (X θ )) shifts along the curve representing the graph of F (X) (the left figure). Put the two figures together: F (X ) θ F θ Xθ − X0 θ(X 1 − X 0 ) θ = = , 1 − Xθ 1 − X 0) X (1 − θ)(X 1−θ Fθ − F0 θ(F 1 − F 0 ) θ = = . 1 − Fθ 1 − F 0) F (1 − θ)(F 1−θ T F (X) X0 Xθ X1 EX F (X) is strictly concave ⇒ if for all X 0 , X 1 and θ ∈ (0, 1), F (X θ ) > F θ . F (X) is concave ⇒ if for all X 0 , X 1 and θ ∈ [0, 1], F (X θ ) ≥ F θ . T T F (X) F (X) is concave F (X) (not strictly) E EX X Notice that these concepts are global concepts. (They have something to do with the whole graph of F , not just the behavior of F nearby a point.) The graph of a concave function can have a flat part. For a strictly concave function, the graph should be curved everywhere except at kink points. F (X) is strictly convex ⇒ if for all X 0 , X 1 and θ ∈ (0, 1), F (X θ ) < F θ . F (X) is convex ⇒ if for all X 0 , X 1 and θ ∈ [0, 1], F (X θ ) ≤ F θ . F (X) is strictly concave 58 F F T T F (X) is strictly convex EX F (X) is convex (not strictly) H EX Remark 1: A linear function is both concave and convex since F θ ≡ F (X θ ). F F F T T $$ $$ T ¨ ¨¨ ¨¨ ¨ ¨ ¨¨ EX ¢ ¢ ¢ ¢ ¢ ¢ a convex ¢ piecewise-linear ¢ function ¢ ¢ ¢ ¢ a concave piecewise-linear function EX EX Remark 2: A piecewise-linear function consists of linear components; for example, the income tax schedule T = f (Y ) is a piecewise-linear function. Other examples are concave F (X) = 2X X≤1 1+X X >1 convex F (X) = X X ≤1 2X − 1 X > 1 In the following theorems, we assume that F ′′ (X) exists for all X. Theorem 1: F (X) is concave, ⇔ F ′′ (X) ≤ 0 for all X. F ′′ (X) < 0 for all X ⇒ F (X) is strictly concave. ¯ ¯ Proof: By Taylor’s theorem, there exist X 0 ∈ [X 0 , X θ ] and X 1 ∈ [X θ , X 1 ] such that 1 ¯ F (X 1 ) = F (X θ ) + F ′ (X θ )(X 1 − X θ ) + F ′′ (X 1 )(X 1 − X θ )2 2 1 ¯ F (X 0 ) = F (X θ ) + F ′ (X θ )(X 0 − X θ ) + F ′′ (X 0 )(X 0 − X θ )2 2 1 ¯ ¯ ⇒ F θ = F (X θ ) + θ(1 − θ)(X 1 − X 0 )2 [F ′′ (X 0 ) + F ′′ (X 1 )]. 2 Theorem 2: If F (X) is concave and F ′ (X 0 ) = 0, then X 0 is a global maximum. If F (X) is strictly concave and F ′ (X 0 ) = 0, then X 0 is a unique global maximum. Proof: By theorem 1, X 0 must be a local maximum. If it is not a global maximum, then there exists X 1 such that F (X 1 ) > F (X 0 ), which implies that F (X θ ) > F (X 0 ) for θ close to 0. Therefore, X 0 is not a local maximum, a contradiction. Remark 1 (boundary/corner solution): The boundary or corner condition F ′ (X) ≤ 0, 59 XF ′ (X) = 0 (or F ′ (X) ≥ 0, (X − a)F ′ (X) = 0) becomes sufficient for global maximum. Remark 2 (minimization problem): For the minimization problem, we replace concavity with convexity and F ′′ (X) < 0 with F ′′ (X) > 0. If F (X) is convex and F ′ (X ∗ ) = 0, then X ∗ is a global minimum. If F (X) is strictly convex and F ′ (X ∗ ) = 0, then X ∗ is a unique global minimum. Remark 3: The sum of two concave functions is concave. The product of two concave function is not necesarily concave. X a is strictly concave if a < 1, strictly convex if a > 1. eX is strictly convex and ln X is strctly concave with X > 0. F T F X a, a > 1 T F X a, 0 < a < 1 T X a, a < 0 EX EX EX F T F eaX T F T −aX 2 + bX + c EX ln X EX EX Remark 4: A concave function does not have to be differentiable, but it must be continuous on the interior points. 7.16 Indeterminate forms and L’Hˆpital’s rule o g(x) , g(a) = h(a) = 0 and g(x) and h(x) be continuous at x = a. f (a) is h(x) 0 not defined because it is . However, limx→a f (x) can be calculated. 0 Let f (x) = g(x) g(x) − g(a) g(a + ∆x) − g(a) g ′ (a) lim f (x) = lim = lim = lim = ′ . x→a x→a h(x) x→a h(x) − h(a) ∆x→0 h(a + ∆x) − h(a) h (a) The same procedure also works for the case with g(a) = h(a) = ∞. g(x) ln[(ax + 1)/2] Example 1: f (x) = = , h(x) x 60 g(0) = h(0) = 0, h′ (x) = 1, g ′(x) = ⇒ h′ (0) = 1 and g ′ (0) = (ln a)ax . ax + 1 ln a ln a , ⇒ limx→0 f (x) = . 2 2 x g(x) Example 2: f (x) = = x , h′ (x) = ex , g ′ (x) = 1. h(x) e 1 ⇒ h′ (∞) = ∞ and g ′ (∞) = 1, ⇒ limx→∞ f (x) = = 0. ∞ g(x) ln x ′ 1 Example 3: f (x) = = , h (x) = 1, g ′ (x) = . h(x) x x ⇒ limx→0+ h′ (x) = 1 and limx→0+ g ′(x) = ∞, ⇒ limx→0+ f (x) = 7.17 Newton’s method 1 = 0. ∞ We can approximate a root x∗ of a nonlinear equation f (x) = 0 using an algorithm called Newton’s method. T f ′ (xn ) = f (xn ) xn − xn+1 f (xn ) . f ′ (xn ) f (xn ) Recursive formula: xn+1 = xn − Ex xn xn+1 x∗ If f (x) is not too strange, we will have limn→∞ xn = x∗ . Usually, two or three steps would be good enough. x3 − 3 x 1 Example: f (x) = x3 − 3, f ′ (x) = 3x2 , xn+1 = xn − = xn − + 2 . 2 3x 3 x 1 5 5 5 9 331 Starting x0 = 1, x1 = 1 − + 1 = ≈ 1.666. x2 = − + = ≈ 1.47. The 3 3 3 9 25 225 √ true value is x∗ = 3 3 ≈ 1.44225. 61 8 Optimization–Multivariate Case x1 ,...,xn Suppose that the objective function has n variables: max F (x1 , . . . , xn ) = F (X). A local maximum X ∗ = (x∗ , . . . , x∗ ): ∃ǫ > 0 such that F (X ∗ ) ≥ F (X) for all X 1 n satisfying xi ∈ (x∗ − ǫ, x∗ + ǫ) ∀i. i i ∂F (X c ) c A critical point X = (xc , . . . , xc ): = 0 ∀i. 1 n ∂xi A global maximum X ∗ : F (X ∗ ) ≥ F (X) ∀X. A unique global maximum X ∗ : F (X ∗ ) > F (X) ∀X = X ∗ . The procedure is the same as that of the single variable case. (1) Use FOC to find critical points; (2) use SOC to check whether a critical point is a local maximum, or show that F (X) is concave so that a critical point must be a global maximum. If we regard variables other than xi as fixed, then it is a single variable maximization problem and, therefore, we have the necessary conditions FOC: ∂F = 0 and ∂xi SOC: ∂2F < 0, i = 1, . . . , n. ∂x2 i However, since there are n×n second order derivatives (the Hessian matrix H(F )) and the SOC above does not consider the cross-derivatives, we have a reason to suspect that the SOC is not sufficient. In the next section we will provide a counter-example and give a true SOC. 8.1 SOC SOC of variable-wise maximization is wrong Example: max F (x1 , x2 ) = −x2 + 4x1 x2 − x2 . 1 2 x1 ,x2 FOC: F1 = −2x1 + 4x2 = 0, F2 = 4x1 − 2x2 = 0, ⇒ x1 = x2 = 0. SOC? F11 = F22 = −2 < 0. x2 T (0,0) is a saddle point. -4 £ £ £ £ £ £ £ £ F T 4 1 When xj = 0, xi = 0 is a maximum. $$$ $$$ $ $ £ $$ E x1 $$ $$ £ $$ -1 $$ 1 £ $$ -4 £ 4 £ £ £ £ £ £ £ -1 £ E xi 62 F (0, 0) = 0 < F (k, k) = 2k 2 for all k = 0. ⇒ (0, 0) is not a local maximum! The true SOC should take into consideration the possibility that when x1 and x2 increase simultaneously F may increase even if individual changes cannot increase F . SOC of sequential maximization: We can solve the maximization problem sequentially. That is, for a given x2 , we can find a x1 such that F (x1 , x2 ) is maximized. The FOC and SOC are F1 = 0 and F11 < 0. The solution depends on x2 , x1 = h(x2 ), i.e., we regard x1 as endogenous variable and x2 as an exogenous variable in the first stage. Using implicit function rule, dx1 /dx2 = h′ (x2 ) = −F12 /F11 . In the second stage we maximize M(x2 ) ≡ F (h(x2 ), x2 ). The FOC is M ′ (x2 ) = F1 h′ + F2 = F2 = 0 (since F1 = 0). The SOC is 2 M ′′ (x2 ) = F1 h′′ + F11 (h′ )2 + 2F12 h′ + F22 = (−F12 + F11 F22 )/F11 < 0. 2 Therefore, the true SOC is: F11 < 0 and F11 F22 − F12 > 0. For the n-variable case, the sequential argument is more complicated and we use Taylor’s expansion. SOC using Taylor’s expansion: To find the true SOC, we can also use Taylor’s theorem to expand F (X) around a critical point X ∗ : F (X) = F (X ∗ ) + F1 (X ∗ )(x1 − x∗ ) + F2 (X ∗ )(x2 − x∗ ) 1 2 1 + (x1 − x∗ , x2 − x∗ ) 1 2 2 F11 (X ∗ ) F12 (X ∗ ) F21 (X ∗ ) F22 (X ∗ ) x1 − x∗ 1 x2 − x∗ 2 + higher order terms. Since X ∗ is a critical point, F1 (X ∗ ) = F2 (X ∗ ) = 0 and we have the approximation for X close to X ∗ : 1 F (X) − F (X ∗ ) ≈ (x1 − x∗ , x2 − x∗ ) 1 2 2 True SOC: v ′ H ∗ v < 0 for all v = 0. F11 (X ∗ ) F12 (X ∗ ) F21 (X ∗ ) F22 (X ∗ ) x1 − x∗ 1 x2 − x∗ 2 1 ≡ v ′ H ∗ v. 2 In the next section, we will derive a systematic method to test the true SOC. 8.2 Quadratic forms and their signs Since vi vj = vj vi , we can assume that aij = aji so that A is symmetrical. 1 −1 v1 2 2 Example 1: (v1 − v2 )2 = v1 − 2v1 v2 + v2 = (v1 , v2 ) . −1 1 v2 A quadratic form in n variables is a second degree homogenous function. a11 · · · a1n v1 n n . . . f (v1 , . . . , vn ) = aij vi vj = (v1 , . . . , vn ) . . . . . . ≡ v ′ Av. . . . i=1 j=1 an1 · · · ann vn 63 0 1 1 0 v1 . v2 Example 2: 2v1 v2 = (v1 , v2 ) v ′ Av v ′ Av v ′ Av v ′ Av (1) (2) (3) (4) 1 0 3 x1 Example 3: x2 + 2x2 + 6x1 x3 = (x1 , x2 , x3 ) 0 2 0 x2 . 1 2 3 0 0 x3 is is is is called called called called negative semidefinite if v ′ Av ≤ 0 for all v ∈ Rn . negative definite if v ′ Av < 0 for all v = 0. positive semidefinite if v ′ Av ≥ 0 for all v ∈ Rn . positive definite if v ′ Av > 0 for all v = 0. 2 2 −v1 − 2v2 < 0, if v1 = 0 or v2 = 0 ⇒ negative. −(v1 − v2 )2 ≤ 0, = 0 if v1 = v2 ⇒ negative semidefinite. (v1 + v2 )2 ≥ 0, = 0 if v1 = −v2 ⇒ positive semidefinite. 2 2 v1 + v2 > 0, if v1 = 0 or v2 = 0 ⇒ positive. > 2 2 > (5) v1 − v2 0 if |v1 | |v | ⇒ neither positive nor negative definite. < < 2 > = (6) v1 v2 0 if sign(v1 ) sign(v2 ) ⇒ neither positive nor negative definite. < = Notice that if v ′ Av is negative (positive) definite then it must be negative (positive) semidefinite. Testing the sign of a quadratic form: a11 a12 v1 2 2 n = 2: v ′ Av = (v1 , v2 ) = a11 v1 + 2a12 v1 v2 + a22 v2 = a21 a22 v2 a11 a2 2 a2 a12 a12 2 2 v2 v1 + 2 v1 v2 + 12 v2 + − 12 + a22 v2 = a11 v1 + a11 a2 a11 a11 11 2 a11 a12 a21 a22 2 + v2 . a11 Negative definite ⇔ a11 < 0 and Positive definite ⇔ a11 > 0 and a11 a21 a11 a21 a12 = a11 a22 − a2 > 0. 12 a22 a12 = a11 a22 − a2 > 0. 12 a22 For negative or positive semidefinite, replace strict inequalities with semi-inequalities. The proofs for them are more difficult and discussed in Lecture 13. 2 2 Example 1: F (v1 , v2 ) = −2v1 + 8v1 v2 − 2v2 = (v1 , v2 ) −2 4 = −12 < 0 ⇒ neither positive nor negative. The matrix is 4 −2 the Hessian of F of the counter-example in section 1. Therefore, the counter-example violates the SOC. −2 < 0 but −2 4 4 −2 v1 v2 , a11 = 64 a11 · · · a1n . . General n: v ′ Av = (v1 , . . . , vn ) . . . . . . . an1 · · · ann a11 a12 a21 a22 + a11 v1 . . = a11 (v1 + · · ·)2 . vn a11 a12 a13 a21 a22 a23 a31 a32 a33 (v3 +· · ·)2 +· · ·+ (v2 +· · ·)2 + a11 a12 a21 a22 a11 . . . a11 · · · a1n . .. . . ··· . an1 · · · ann a(n−1)1 ··· a1(n−1) . .. . . . · · · a(n−1)(n−1) 2 vn . a11 · · · a1k . .. . k-th order principle minor of A: A(k) ≡ . . . , k = 1, . . . , n. . . ak1 · · · akk (2) |A | |A(3) | |A(n) | Negative definite ⇔ A(1) = a11 < 0, (1) < 0, (2) < 0, . . ., (n−1) < 0. |A | |A | |A | (2) (3) (n) |A | |A | |A | Positive definite ⇔ A(1) = a11 > 0, (1) > 0, (2) > 0, . . ., (n−1) > 0. |A | |A | |A | a11 a12 Negative definite ⇔ |A(1) | = a11 < 0, |A(2) | = > 0, |A(3) | = a21 a22 a11 · · · a1n a11 a12 a13 . .. . n (n) n . a21 a22 a23 < 0, · · ·, (−1) |A | = (−1) > 0. . . . . a31 a32 a33 an1 · · · ann a11 a12 Positive definite ⇔ |A(1) | = a11 > 0, |A(2) | = > 0, |A(3) | = a21 a22 a11 · · · a1n a11 a12 a13 . .. . (n) . a21 a22 a23 > 0, · · ·, |A | = > 0. . . . . a31 a32 a33 an1 · · · ann The conditions for semidefinite are more complicated and will be discussed in Lecture 13 using the concept of eigenvalues of a square matrix. 8.3 SOC again From the last two sections, the SOC for a local maximum can be summarized as: F11 (X ∗ ) F12 (X ∗ ) SOC: v ′ HF (X ∗ )v is negative definite ⇒ F11 (X ∗ ) < 0, = F21 (X ∗ ) F22 (X ∗ ) F11 (X ∗ ) F12 (X ∗ ) F13 (X ∗ ) 2 F11 F22 − F12 > 0, F21 (X ∗ ) F22 (X ∗ ) F23 (X ∗ ) < 0, . . . F31 (X ∗ ) F32 (X ∗ ) F33 (X ∗ ) 2 Example: max F (x1 , x2 ) = 3x1 + 3x1 x2 − 3x1 − x3 . (A cubic function in 2 vari2 ables.) 65 FOC: F1 = 3 + 3x2 − 6x1 = 0 and F2 = 3x1 − 3x2 = 0. 2 1 x1 1 Two critical points: = 41 and . x2 1 − 2 F11 (X) F12 (X) −6 3 Hessian matrix: H(x1 , x2 ) = = ; |H 1 (X)| = F21 (X) F22 (X) 3 −6x2 −6 3 F11 (X) = −6 < 0, |H 2(X)| = = 36x2 − 9. 3 −6x2 1 1 1 4 |H 2 ( , − )| = −27 < 0 ⇒ 1 is not a local max. 4 2 − 2 1 |H 2 (1, 1)| = 27 > 0 ⇒ is a local max. F (1, 1) = 2. It is not a global maximum 1 because F →∞ when x2 → − ∞. 2 Remark 1: F11 < 0 and F11 F22 − F12 > 0 together implies F22 < 0. Remark 2: If |H k (X ∗ )| = 0 for some 1 ≤ k ≤ n then X ∗ is a degenerate critical point. Although we can still check whether v ′ Hv is negative semidefinite, it is insufficient for a local maximum. We have to check the third or higher order derivatives to determine whether X ∗ is a local maximum. It is much more difficult than the single variable case with F ′′ = 0. 8.4 Joint products 2 2 Example: C(q1 , q2 ) = 2q1 + 3q2 − q1 q2 FOC: p1 − 4q1 + q2 = 0, p2 + q1 − 6q2 = 0 ⇒ supply functions q1 = (6p1 + p2 )/23 and q2 = (p1 + 4p2 )/23. −C11 −C12 −4 1 SOC: −C11 = −4 < 0, = 23 > 0. = −C21 −C22 1 −6 A competitive producer produces two joint products. (eg., gasoline and its by products or cars and tructs, etc.) Cost function: C(q1 , q2 ). Profit function: Π(q1 , q2 ; p1 , p2 ) = p1 q1 + p2 q2 − C(q1 , q2 ). FOC: Π1 = p1 − C1 = 0, Π2 = p2 − C2 = 0; or pi = MCi . −C11 −C12 SOC: Π11 = −C11 < 0, ≡ ∆ > 0. −C21 −C22 Comparative statics: Total differential of FOC: C11 C12 C21 C22 dq1 dq2 = dp1 dp2 ∂q1 ⇒ ∂p1 ∂q2 ∂p1 ∂q1 ∂p2 = 1 ∂q2 ∆ ∂p2 C22 −C12 −C21 C11 . 66 SOC ⇒ C11 > 0, C22 > 0, ∆ > 0 ⇒ ∂q2 ∂q1 > 0, > 0. ∂p1 ∂p2 ∂q1 ∂q2 and are positive if the joint products are beneficially to each other in the ∂p2 ∂p1 production so that C12 < 0. 8.5 Monopoly price discrimination Example: f1 = a − bq1 , f2 = α − βq2 , and C(Q) = 0.5Q2 = 0.5(q1 + q2 )2 . ′ ′ ′′ ′′ f1 = −b, f2 = −β, f1 = f2 = 0, C ′ = Q = q1 + q2 , and C ′′ = 1. 1 + 2b 1 q1 a FOC: a − 2bq1 = q1 + q2 = α − 2βq2 ⇒ = 1 1 + 2β q2 α 1 q1 a(1 + 2β) − α ⇒ = . q2 (1 + 2b)(1 + 2β) − 1 α(1 + 2b) − a SOC: −2b − 1 < 0 and ∆ = (1 + 2b)(1 + 2β) − 1 > 0. p T A monopoly sells its product in two separable markets. Cost function: C(Q) = C(q1 + q2 ) Inverse market demands: p1 = f1 (q1 ) and p2 = f2 (q2 ) Profit function: Π(q1 , q2 ) = p1 q1 + p2 q2 − C(q1 + q2 ) = q1 f1 (q1 ) + q2 f2 (q2 ) − C(q1 + q2 ) ′ ′ FOC: Π1 = f1 (q1 ) + q1 f1 (q1 ) −C ′ (q1 + q2 ) = 0, Π2 = f2 (q2 ) + q2 f2 (q2 ) −C ′ (q1 + q2 ) = 0; or MR1 = MR2 = MC. ′ ′′ 2f1 + q1 f1 − C ′′ −C ′′ ′ ′′ SOC: Π11 = 2f1 + q1 f1 − C ′′ < 0, ≡ ∆ > 0. ′′ ′ ′′ −C 2f2 + q2 f2 − C ′′ MC∗ d d d d d d MR1+2 d d MR d 2 d MR1 ∗ q1 ∗ q2 MC MC = MR1+2 ⇒ Q∗ , MC∗ ∗ MC∗ = MR1 ⇒ q1 ∗ MC∗ = MR2 ⇒ q2 Q ∗ Eq 8.6 SR supply vs LR supply - Le Chˆtelier principle a A competitive producer employs a variable input x1 and a fixed input x2 . Assume that the input prices are both equal to 1, w1 = w2 = 1. Production function: q = f (x1 , x2 ), assume MPi = fi > 0, fii < 0, fij > 0, 67 2 f11 f22 > f12 . Profit function: Π(x1 , x2 ; p) = pf (x1 , x2 ) − x1 − x2 . Short-run problem (only x1 can be adjusted, x2 is fixed): SR FOC: Π1 = pf1 − 1 = 0, or w1 = VMP1 . SOC: Π11 = pf11 < 0, 2 dx1 −f1 dq s −f1 −1 Comparative statics: f1 dp+pf11 dx1 = 0 ⇒ = > 0, = = 3 > 0. dp pf11 dp pf11 p f11 Long-run problem (both x1 and x2 can be adjusted): LR FOC: Π1 = pf1 − 1 = 0, Π2 = pf2 − 1 = 0; or wi = VMPi . pf11 pf12 SOC: Π11 = pf11 < 0, ≡ ∆ > 0. pf21 pf22 f1 dp pf11 pf12 dx1 0 Comparative statics: + = f2 dp pf21 pf22 dx2 0 −1 dq L −(f11 + f22 − 2f12 ) dx1 /dp f1 f22 − f2 f12 ⇒ = , = 2 2 dx2 /dp f2 f11 − f1 f21 p(f11 f22 − f12 ) dp p3 (f11 f22 − f12 ) dq s dq L > . Le Chˆtelier principle: a dp dp Example: f (x1 , x2 ) = 3x1 x2 (homogenous of degree 2/3) −2/3 1/3 1/3 −2/3 LR FOC: px1 x2 = 1 = px1 x2 ⇒ x1 = x2 = p3 q L = 3p2 . −2/3 SR FOC (assuming x2 = 1): px1 ¯ = 1 ⇒ x1 = p3/2 q s = 3p1/2 . L s η (LR supply elasticity) = 2 > η (SR supply elasticity) = 1/2. L p π ¨ π (p) s 0.5 T T ¨ S (p) = 3p ¨ ¨ ¨¨ ¨¨ ¨¨ 1/3 1/3 π s (p; x2 ) ¯ h(p) S L (p) = 3p2 Eq Ep p ¯ Envelop theorem, Hotelling’s lemma, and Le Chˆtelier principle a From the SR problem we first derive the SR variable input demand function x1 = x1 (p, x2 ). ¯ Then the SR supply function is obtained by substituting into the production function q s = f (x1 (p, x2 ), x2 ) ≡ S s (p; x2 ). ¯ ¯ ¯ The SR profit function is π s (p, x2 ) = pq s − x1 (p, x2 ) − x2 . ¯ ¯ ¯ ∂π s Hotelling’s lemma: By envelop theorem, = S s (p, x2 ). ¯ ∂p From the LR problem we first derive the input demand functions x1 = x1 (p) and x2 = x2 (p). Then the LR supply function is obtained by substituting into the production function 68 q L = f (x1 (p), x2 (p)) ≡ S L (p). The LR profit function is π L (p) = pq L − x1 (p) − x2 (p). ∂π L (Also Hotelling’s lemma) By envelop theorem, = S L (p). ∂p Notice that π L (p) = π s (p; x2 (p)). Let x2 = x2 (¯), define h(p) ≡ π L (p) − π s (p, x2 ). h(p) ≥ 0 because in the LR, ¯ p ¯ the producer can adjust x2 to achieve a higher profit level. Also, h(¯) = 0 because π L (¯) = π s (¯; x2 (¯)) = π s (¯; x2 ). p p p p p ¯ ∂2 πL ∂2πs ′′ Therefore, h(p) has a minimum at p = p and the SOC is h (¯) > 0 = ¯ p − 2 > 0, ∂p2 ∂p which implies dq L dq s Le Chˆtelier principle: a − > 0. dp dp 8.7 Concavity and Convexity Similar to the single variable case, we define the concepts of concavity and convexity for 2-variable functions F (X) = F (x1 , x2 ) by defining G+ , G− ⊂ R2 s follows. F F G+ ≡ {(x1 , x2 , y)| y ≥ F (x1 , x2 ), (x1 , x2 ) ∈ R2 }, F G− ≡ {(x1 , x2 , y)| y ≤ F (x1 , x2 ), (x1 , x2 ) ∈ R2 }. F If G+ (G− ) is a convex set, then we say F (X) is a convex function (a concave funcF F tion). If F (X) is defined only for nonnegative values x1 , x2 ≥ 0, the definition is similar. (The extension to n-variable functions is similar.) Equivalently, given X 0 = F 1 ≡ F (X 1 ), we define x0 1 x0 2 , X1 = x1 1 x1 2 ≡ , 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1, F 0 ≡ F (X 0 ), xθ 1 xθ 2 , F (X θ ) = F ((1 − θ)X 0 + X θ ≡ (1 − θ)X 0 + θX 1 = θX 1 ) F θ ≡ (1 − θ)F (X 0 ) + θF (X 1 ) = (1 − θ)F 0 + θF 1 . x2 T (1 − θ)x0 + θx1 1 1 (1 − θ)x0 + θx1 2 2 x0 2 xθ 2 x1 2 d d Xθ d d d d X1 X0 X θ is located on the straight line connecting X 0 and X 1 , when θ shifts from 0 to 1, E x1 x0 1 xθ 1 x1 1 X θ shifts from X 0 to X 1 . On 3-dimensional (x1 –x2 –F ) space, (X θ , F θ ) is located on the straight line connecting (X 0 , F 0 ) and (X 1 , F 1), when θ shifts from 0 to 1, (X θ , F θ ) shifts from (X 0 , F 0 ) to (X 1 , F 1 ). On the other hand, (X θ , F (X θ )) shifts along the surface representing the graph of F (X). 69 F (X) F (X) F (X) F (X) is is is is strictly concave ⇒ if for all X 0 , X 1 and θ ∈ (0, 1), F (X θ ) > F θ . concave ⇒ if for all X 0 , X 1 and θ ∈ [0, 1], F (X θ ) ≥ F θ . strictly convex ⇒ if for all X 0 , X 1 and θ ∈ (0, 1), F (X θ ) < F θ . convex ⇒ if for all X 0 , X 1 and θ ∈ [0, 1], F (X θ ) ≤ F θ . 1/3 1/3 Example: 9x1 x2 . Assume that F is twice differentiable. Theorem 1: F (X) is concave, ⇔ v ′ HF v is negative semidefinite for all X. v ′ HF v is negative definite for all X ⇒ F (X) is strictly concave. ¯ ¯ Proof: By Taylor’s theorem, there exist X 0 ∈ [X 0 , X θ ] and X 1 ∈ [X θ , X 1 ] such that 1 ¯ F (X 1) = F (X θ ) + ∇F (X θ )(X 1 − X θ ) + (X 1 − X θ )′ HF (X 1 )(X 1 − X θ ) 2 1 ¯ F (X 0) = F (X θ ) + ∇F (X θ )(X 0 − X θ ) + (X 0 − X θ )′ HF (X 0 )(X 0 − X θ ) 2 θ(1 − θ) 1 ¯ ¯ ⇒ F θ = F (X θ ) + (X − X 0 )′ [HF (X 0 ) + HF (X 1 )](X 1 − X 0 ). 2 Theorem 2: If F (X) is concave and ∇F (X 0 ) = 0, then X 0 is a global maximum. If F (X) is strictly concave and ∇F (X 0 ) = 0, then X 0 is a unique global maximum. Proof: By theorem 1, X 0 must be a local maximum. If it is not a global maximum, then there exists X 1 such that F (X 1 ) > F (X 0 ), which implies that F (X θ ) > F (X 0 ) for θ close to 0. Therefore, X 0 is not a local maximum, a contradiction. Remark 1 (boundary or corner solution): The boundary or corner condition Fi (X) ≤ 0, xi Fi (X) = 0 (or Fi (X) ≥ 0, (xi − ai )Fi (X) = 0) becomes sufficient for global maximum. Remark 2 (minimization problem): For the minimization problem, we replace concavity with convexity and negative definite with positive definite. If F (X) is convex and ∇F (X ∗ ) = 0, then X ∗ is a global minimum. If F (X) is strictly convex and ∇F (X ∗ ) = 0, then X ∗ is a unique global minimum. 8.8 Learning and utility maximization Consumer B’s utility function is U = u(x, k) + m − h(k), x, m, k ≥ 0, where x is the quantity of commodity X consumed, k is B’s knowledge regard2 ing the consumption of X, m is money, u(x, k) is the utility obtained, ∂ u < 0, ∂x2 ∂2u > 0 (marginal utility of X increases with k), and h(k) is the disutility of acquir∂x∂k ing/maintaining k, h′ > 0, h′′ > 0. Assume that B has 100 dollar to spend and the price of X is Px = 1 so that m = 100 − x and U = u(x, k) + 100 − x − h(k). Assume 70 also that k is fixed in the short run. The short run utility maximization problem is ∂u ∂2u max u(x, k) + 100 − x − h(k), ⇒ FOC: − 1 = 0, SOC: < 0. x ∂x ∂x2 The short run comparative static dx is derived from FOC as dk ∂ 2 u/∂x2 dx =− 2 > 0, dk ∂ u/∂x∂k that is, consumer B will consume more of X if B’s knowledge of X increases. In the long run consumer B will change k to attain higher utility level. The long run utility maximization problem is max u(x, k) + 100 − x − h(k), x,k ⇒ FOC: ∂u − 1 = 0, ∂x ∂u − h′ (k) = 0. ∂k The SOC is satisfied if we assume that u(x, k) is concave and h(k) is convex (h′′ (k) > 0), because F (x, k) ≡ u(x, k) + 100 − x − h(k), x, k ≥ 0 is strictly concave then. Consider now the specific case when u(x, k) = 3x2/3 k 1/3 and h(k) = 0.5k 2 . 1. Calculate consumer B’s short run consumption of X, xs = x(k). (In this part, you may ignore the nonnegative constraint m = 100 − x ≥ 0 and the possibility of a corner solution.) x = 1/(8k). 2. Calculate the long run consumption of X, xL . x = 32 3. Derive the short run value function V (k) ≡ u(x(k), k) + 100 − x(k) − h(k). 4. Solve the maximization problem maxk V (k). k = 4. 5. Explain how the SOC is satisfied and why the solution is the unique global maximum. (demand functions) Consider now the general case when Px = p so that U = 3x2/3 k 1/3 + 100 − px − 0.5k 2 . 1. Calculate consumer B’s short run demand function of X, xs = x(p; k). (Warning: There is a nonnegative constraint m = 100 − px ≥ 0 and you have to consider both interior and corner cases.) √ √ xs (p) = 8kp−3 (100/p) if p ≤ 2k/5 (p < 2k/5). 2. Calculate the long run demand function of X, xL (p). and the optimal level of K, kL (p). (Both interior and corner cases should be considered too.) xL (p) = 32p−5 (100/p) if p > (8/25)1/4 (p < (8/25)1/4), kL (p) = [xL (p)]2/5 . 71 8.9 Homogeneous and homothetic functions A homogeneous function of degree k is f (x1 , . . . , xn ) such that f (hx1 , . . . , hxn ) = hk f (x1 , . . . , xn ) ∀h > 0. If f is homogeneous of degree k1 and g homogeneous of degree k2 , then f g is homogef neous of degree k1 + k2 , is homogeneous of degree k1 − k2 , and f m is homogeneous g of degree mk1 . x2 x2 If Q = F (x1 , x2 ) is homogeneous of degree 1, then Q = x1 F (1, ) ≡ x1 f . If x1 x1 x2 x2 m = H(x1 , x2 ) is homogeneous of degree 0, then m = H(1, ) ≡ h . x1 x1 Euler theorem: If f (x1 , . . . , xn ) is homogeneous of degree k, then x1 f1 + . . . + xn fn = kf If f is homogeneous of degree k, then fi is homogenous of degree k − 1. Examples: 1. Cobb-Douglas function Q = Axα xβ is homogeneous of degree α + β. 1 2 k 2. CES function Q = {axρ + bxρ } ρ is homogenous of degree k. 1 2 3. A quadratic form x′ Ax is homogeneous of degree 2. 4. Leontief function Q = min {ax1 , bx2 } is homogeneous of degree 1. Homothetic functions: If f is homogeneous and g = H(f ), H is a monotonic increasing function, then g is called a homothetic function. Example: Q = α ln x1 + β ln x2 = ln xα xβ 1 2 is homothetic. x2 . x1 The MRS of a homothetic function depends only on the ratio 8.10 Problems 1. Use Newton’s method to find the root of the nonlinear equation X 3 +2X +2 = 0 accurate to 2 digits. 1 − e−aX e2X − eX 1 − 2−X 2. Find (a) lim , (b) lim+ , (c) lim . X→0 X→0 X→0 X X X 3. Given the total cost function C(Q) = eaQ+b , use L’hˆpital’s rule to find the o + AVC at Q = 0 . 4. Let z = x1 x2 + x2 + 3x2 + x2 x3 + x2 . 1 2 3 (a) Use matrix multiplication to represent z. (b) Determine whether z is positive definite or negative definite. (c) Find the extreme value of z. Check whether it is a maximum or a minimum. 72 Q3 + K, where K 3K 5. The cost function of a competitive producer is C(Q; K) = is, say, the plant size (a fixed factor in the short run). (a) At which output level, the SAC curve attains a minimum? (b) Suppose that the equilibrium price is p = 100. The profit is Π = 100Q − Q3 − K. For a given K, find the supply quantity Q(K) such that SR 3K profit is maximized. (c) Calculate the SR maximizing profit π(K). (d) Find the LR optimal K = K ∗ to maximize π(K). (e) Calculate the LR supply quantity Q∗ = Q(K ∗ ). (f) Now solve the 2-variable maximization problem Q3 max Π(Q, K) = pQ − C(Q) = 100Q − − K. Q,K≥0 3K and show that Π(Q, K) is concave so that the solution is the unique global maximum. 6. A competitive firm produces two joint products. The total cost function is 2 2 C(q1 , q2 ) = 2q1 + 3q2 − 4q1 q2 . (a) Use the first order conditions for profit maximization to derive the supply functions. (b) Check that the second order conditions are satisfied. 7. Check whether the function f (x, y) = ex+y is concave, convex, or neither. 8. (a) Check whether f (x, y) = 2 ln x+3 ln y −x−2y is concave, convex, or neither. (Assume that x > 0 and y > 0.) (b) Find the critical point of f . (c) Is the critical point a local maximum, a global maximum, or neither? 9. Suppose that a monopoly can produce any level of output at a constant marginal cost of $c per unit. Assume that the monopoly sells its goods in two different markets which are separated by some distance. The demand curve in the first market is given by Q1 = exp[−aP1 ] and the curve in the second market is given by Q2 = exp[−bP2 ]. If the monopolist wants to maximize its total profits, what level of output should be produced in each market and what price will prevail in each market? Check that your answer is the unique global maximum. (Hints: 1. P1 = −(1/a) ln Q1 and P2 = −(1/b) ln Q2 . 2. Π = P1 Q1 + P2 Q2 − (Q1 + Q2 )c = −(1/a)Q1 ln Q1 − (1/b)Q2 ln Q2 − (Q1 + Q2 )c is strictly concave.) 10. The production function of a competitive firm is given by q = f (x1 , x2 ) = 1 1 3 3 3x1 x2 , where x1 is a variable input and x2 is a fixed input. Assume that the prices of the output and the fixed input are p = w2 = 1. In the short run, the amount of the fixed input is given by x2 = x2 . The profit function of the ¯ competitive firm is given by π = f (x1 , x2 ) − w1 x1 − x2 . ¯ ¯ 73 (a) State the FOC for the SR profit maximization and calculate the SR input S S 1 ∂x demand function xS = x1 (w1 ) and the SR input demand elasticity wS ∂w11 . 1 x 1 (b) Now consider the LR situation when x2 can be adjusted. State the FOC for LR profit maximization and calculate the LR input demand funtion L w1 ∂x xL = xL (w1 ) and the LR input demand elasticity xL ∂w11 . 1 1 1 (c) Verify the Le Chˆtelier principle: a L w1 ∂x1 xL ∂w1 1 > S w1 ∂x1 xS ∂w1 1 . (d) Show that the LR profit is a strictly concave function of (x1 , x2 ) for x1 , x2 > 0 and therefore the solution must be the unique global maximum. 11. Let U(x, y) = xa y + xy 2 , x, y, a > 0. (a) For what value(s) of a U(x, y) is homogeneous?. (b) For what value(s) of a U(x, y) is homothetic? 74 9 Optimization and Equality Constraints and Nonlinear Programming In some maximization problems, the agents can choose only values of (x1 , . . . , xn ) that satisfy certain equalities. For example, a consumer has a budget constraint p1 x1 + · · · + pn xn = m. x1 ,...,xn max U(x) = U(x1 , . . . , xn ) subject to p1 x1 + · · · + pn xn = m. The procedure is the same as before. (1) Use FOC to find critical points; (2) use SOC to check whether a critical point is a local maximum, or show that U(X) is quasi-concave so that a critical point must be a global maximum. Define B = {(x1 , . . . , xn ) such that p1 x1 + · · · + pn xn = m}. A local maximum X ∗ = (x∗ , . . . , x∗ ): ∃ǫ > 0 such that U(X ∗ ) ≥ U(X) for all X ∈ B 1 n satisfying xi ∈ (x∗ − ǫ, x∗ + ǫ) ∀i. i i A critical point: A X ∗ ∈ B satisfying the FOC for a local maximum. A global maximum X ∗ : F (X ∗ ) ≥ F (X) ∀X ∈ B. A unique global maximum X ∗ : F (X ∗ ) > F (X) ∀X ∈ B, X = X ∗ . To define the concept of a critical point, we have to know what is the FOC first. 9.1 FOC and SOC for a constraint maximization Consider the 2-variable utility maximization problem: max U(x1 , x2 ) subject to p1 x1 + p2 x2 = m. x1 ,x2 m − p1 x1 dx2 p1 = h(x1 ), = − = h′ (x1 ), and it p2 dx1 p2 becomes a single variable maximization problem: Using the budget constraint, x2 = max U x1 x1 , m − p1 x1 p2 , FOC: dU p1 = U1 + U2 − dx1 p2 p1 p2 2 = 0, SOC: d2 U < 0. dx2 1 d2 U p1 = U11 − 2 U12 + 2 dx1 p2 By FOC, U1 U2 = ≡ λ (MU of $1). p1 p2 U22 = −1 p2 2 0 −p1 −p2 −p1 U11 U12 . −p2 U21 U22 FOC: U1 = p1 λ, U2 = p2 λ, SOC: Alternatively, we can define Lagrangian: 0 U1 U2 U1 U11 U12 U2 U21 U22 > 0. L ≡ U(x1 , x2 ) + λ(m − p1 x1 − p2 x2 ) 75 ∂L ∂L ∂L = U1 − λp1 = 0, L2 = = U2 − λp2 = 0, Lλ = = ∂x1 ∂x2 ∂λ m − p1 x1 − p2 x2 = 0. 0 −p1 −p2 SOC: −p1 L11 L12 > 0. −p2 L21 L22 FOC: L1 = max F (x1 , x2 ) subject to g(x1 , x2 ) = 0. x1 ,x2 general 2-variable with 1-constraint case: Using the constraint, x2 = h(x1 ), variable maximization problem: max F (x1 , h(x1 )) FOC: x1 dx2 g1 = − = h′ (x1 ), and it becomes a single dx1 g2 dF d2 F = F1 + F2 h′ (x1 ) = 0, SOC: < 0. dx1 dx2 1 d2 F d 2 = (F1 + F2 h′ ) = F11 + 2h′ F12 + (h′ ) F22 + F2 h′′ 2 dx1 dx1 h′′ = ⇒ d2 F = dx2 1 0 d dx1 − g1 g2 = −1 g11 + 2g12 h′ + g22 (h′ )2 . g2 F2 F2 g12 h′ + F22 − g22 (h′ )2 g2 g2 0 g1 g2 g1 g2 F2 F2 F11 − g11 F12 − g12 g2 g2 F2 F2 F21 − g21 F22 − g22 g2 g2 F11 − F2 g11 g2 + 2 F12 − −h′ 1 F2 F2 −h′ F11 − g11 F12 − g12 −1 g2 g2 =− = 2 g2 F2 F2 1 F21 − g21 F22 − g22 g2 g2 F2 F1 By FOC, = ≡ λ (Lagrange multiplier). g1 g2 Alternatively, we can define Lagrangian: L ≡ F (x1 , x2 ) − λg(x1 , x2 ) FOC: L1 = 0. SOC: ∂L ∂L ∂L = F1 − λg1 = 0, L2 = = F2 − λg2 = 0, Lλ = = −g(x1 , x2 ) = ∂x1 ∂x2 ∂λ > 0. n-variable 1-constraint case: x1 ,...,xn 0 g1 g2 g1 L11 L12 g2 L21 L22 max F (x1 , . . . , xn ) subject to g(x1 , . . . , xn ) = 0. L ≡ F (x1 , . . . , xn ) − λg(x1 , . . . , xn ) 76 FOC: Li = SOC: ∂L ∂L = Fi − λgi = 0, i = 1, . . . , n, Lλ = = −g(x1 , . . . , xn ) = 0. ∂xi ∂λ 0 −g1 −g2 −g3 0 −g1 −g2 0 −g1 −g1 L11 L12 L13 < 0, −g1 L11 L12 > 0 < 0, etc. −g1 L11 −g2 L21 L22 L23 −g2 L21 L22 −g3 L31 L32 L33 9.2 Examples 2 Example 1: max F (x1 , x2 ) = −x1 − x2 subject to x1 + x2 = 1. 2 L = −x2 − x2 + λ(1 − x1 − x2 ). 1 2 FOC: L1 = −2x1 − λ = 0, 2 = 2 − λ = 0 and Lλ = 1 − 2x1 − 2x2 = 0. L −2x 1 x1 2 Critical point: = 1 , λ = −1. x2 2 0 1 1 SOC: 1 −2 0 = 4 > 0. 1 0 −2 1/2 ⇒ is a local maximum. 1/2 x2 T d d dr d d d x2 T E x1 d d d dr d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d d r d d d d d d d d E x1 Example 2: max F (x1 , x2 ) = x1 + x2 subject to x2 + x2 = 1. 1 2 L = x1 + x2 + λ(1 − x2 − x2 ). 1 2 FOC: L1 = 1 − 2λx1 = 0, L2 = 1 − 2λx2 = 0 and Lλ = 1 − x2 − x2 = 0. 1 2 √ √ Two critical points: x1 = x2 = λ = 1/ 2 and x1 = x2 = λ = −1/ 2. 0 −2x1 −2x2 0 SOC: −2x1 −2λ = 8λ(x2 + x2 ). 1 2 −2x2 0 −2λ √ √ ⇒ x1 = x2 = λ = 1/ 2 is a local maximum and x1 = x2 = λ = −1/ 2 is a local minimum. 77 9.3 Cost minimization and cost function 1−a min C(x1 , x2 ; w1, w2 ) = w1 x1 + w2 x2 subject to xa x2 = q, 0 < a < 1. 1 L = w1 x1 + w2 x2 + λ(q − xa x1−a ). 1 2 FOC: L1 = w1 − aλxa−1 x1−a = 0, L2 = w2 − (1 − a)λxa x−a = 0, Lλ = q − xa x1−a = 0. 1 2 1 2 1 2 1−a a ax2 aw2 (1 − a)w1 w1 ⇒ = ⇒ x1 = q , x2 = q . w2 (1 − a)x1 (1 − a)w1 aw2 SOC: 0 1−a −axa−1 x2 1 −(1 − a)xa x−a 1 2 1−a a −axa−1 x2 −(1 − a)x1 x−a 1 2 a−2 1−a a(1 − a)λx1 x2 −a(1 − a)λxa−1 x−a 1 2 a−1 −a −a(1 − a)λx1 x2 a(1 − a)λxa x−a−1 1 2 1−a a a(1 − a)q 3 λ =− < 0. (x1 x2 )2 (1 − a)w1 , x2 = q is a local minimum. aw2 1−a a a 1−a a 1−a The total cost is C(w1 , w2 , q) = q + w1 w2 . 1−a a 9.4 Utility maximization and demand function aw2 ⇒ x1 = q (1 − a)w1 max U(x1 , x2 ) = a ln x1 + b ln x2 subject to p1 x1 + p2 x2 = m. L = a ln x1 + b ln x2 + λ(m − p1 x1 − p2 x2 ). a b − λp1 = 0, L2 = − λp2 = 0 and Lλ = m − p1 x1 − p2 x2 = 0. FOC: L1 = x1 x2 a x2 p1 am bm ⇒ = ⇒ x1 = , x2 = b x1 p2 (a + b)p1 (a + b)p2 0 −p1 −p2 −a ap2 bp2 −p1 0 SOC: = 22 + 21 > 0. x2 1 x1 x2 −b −p2 0 x2 2 am bm ⇒ x1 = , x2 = is a local maximum. (a + b)p1 (a + b)p2 9.5 Quasi-concavity and quasi-convexity As discussed in the intermediate microeconomics course, if the MRS is strictly decreasing along an indifference curve (indifference curve is convex toward the origin), then the utility maximization has a unique solution. A utility function U(x1 , x2 ) U1 is quasi-concave if MRS (= ) is decreasing along every indifference curve. In U2 case MRS is strictly decreasing, the utility function is strictly quasi-concave. If U(x1 , x2 ) is (strictly) quasi-concave, then a critical point must be a (unique) global maximum. Two ways to determine whether U(x1 , x2 ) is quasi-concave: (1) the set {(x1 , x2 ) ∈ ¯ ¯ R2 U(x1 , x2 ) ≥ U } is convex for all U . (Every indifference curve is convex toward the 78 origin.) d (2) dx1 curve.) − U1 U2 > 0. (MRS is strictly decreasing along every indifference ¯ U (x1 ,x2 )=U + In sections 6.14 and 7.7 we used F (X) to define two sets, GF and G− , and we say F − that F (X) is concave (convex) if GF (G+ ) is a convex set. Now we say that F (X) is F + quasi-concave (quasi-convex) if every y-cross-section of G− (GF ) is a convex set. A F y-cross-section is formally defined as G− (¯) ≡ {(x1 , x2 )| F (x1 , x2 ) ≥ y } ⊂ R2 , ¯ F y G+ (¯) ≡ {(x1 , x2 )| F (x1 , x2 ) ≤ y } ⊂ R2 . ¯ F y Clearly, G− is the union of all G− (¯): G− = ∪y G− (¯). ¯ F y F F y F Formal definition: F (x1 , . . . , xn ) is quasi-concave if ∀X 0 , X 1 ∈ A and 0 ≤ θ ≤ 1, F (X θ ) ≥ min{F (X 0), F (X 1 )}. F (x1 , . . . , xn ) is strictly quasi-concave if ∀X 0 = X 1 ∈ A and 0 < θ < 1, F (X θ ) > min{F (X 0), F (X 1 )}. x2 x2 T T E x1 d d d d d d E x1 If F is (strictly) concave, then F must be (strictly) quasi-concave. Proof: If F (X θ ) < min{F (X 0), F (X 1 )}, then F (X θ ) < (1 − θ)F (X 0 ) + θF (X 1 ). Geometrically, if G− is convex, then G− (¯) must be convex for every y . ¯ F F y If F is quasi-concave, it is not necessarily that F is concave. Counterexample: F (x1 x2 ) = x1 x2 , x1 , x2 > 0 is strictly quasi-concave but not concave. In this case, every G− (¯) is convex but still G− is not convex. F y F 0 F1 , |B 2 | ≡ F1 F11 0 F1 F2 F1 F11 F12 , |B 3 | ≡ F2 F21 F22 0 F1 F2 F3 F1 F11 F12 F13 , F2 F21 F22 F23 F3 F31 F32 F33 Bordered Hessian: |B 1 | ≡ etc. Theorem 1: Suppose that F is twice differentiable. If F is quasi-concave, then |B 2 | ≥ 0, |B 3 | ≤ 0, etc. Conversely, if |B 1 | < 0, |B 2 | > 0, |B 3 | < 0, etc., then F is strictly quasi-concave. |B 2 | dMRS Proof (n = 2): = 3 and therefore F is quasi-concave if and only if |B 2 | ≥ 0. dx1 F2 79 Consider the following maximization problem with a linear constraint. x1 ,...,xn max F (x1 , . . . , xn ) subject to a1x1 + · · · + an xn = b. Theorem 2: If F is (strictly) quasi-concave and X 0 satisfies FOC, then X 0 is a (unique) global maximum. Proof: By theorem 1, X 0 must be a local maximum. Suppose there exists X 1 satisfying the linear constraint with U(X 1 ) > U(X 0 ). Then U(X θ ) > U(X 0 ), a contradiction. Theorem 3: A monotonic increasing transformation of a quasi-concave function is a quasi-concave function. A quasi-concave function is a monotonic increasing transformation of a concave function. Proof: A monotonic increasing transformation does not change the sets {(x1 , x2 ) ∈ ¯ R2 U(x1 , x2 ) ≥ U}. To show the opposite, suppose that f (x1 , x2 ) is quasi-concave. Define a monotonic transformation as g(x1 , x2 ) = H(f (x1 , x2 )) where H −1(g) = f (x, x). 9.6 Elasticity of Substitution Consider a production function Q = F (x1 , x2 ). w1 F1 x2 ¯ Cost minimization ⇒ = ≡ θ. Let ≡ r. On an isoquant F (x1 , x2 ) = Q, w2 F2 x1 θ dr . there is a relationship r = φ(θ). The elasticity of substitution is defined as σ ≡ r dθ w1 If the input price ratio θ = increases by 1%, a competitive producer will increase w2 x2 its input ratio r = by σ%. x1 k 1 . Example: For a CES function Q = {axρ + bxρ } ρ , σ = 1 2 1−ρ 9.7 Problems a11 a12 a21 a22 0 c1 c2 , B = c1 a11 a12 , and C = c2 a21 a22 −c2 c1 . 1. Let A = (b) Calculate the product C ′ AC. Does |B| have any relationship with C ′ AC? 2. Consider the utility function U(x1 , x2 ) = xα xβ . 1 2 (a) Calculate the marginal utilities U1 = (b) Calculate the hessian matrix H = ∂U ∂U and U2 = . ∂x1 ∂x2 U11 U12 . U21 U22 (a) Calculate the determinant |B|. 80 0 U1 U2 (c) Calculate the determinant of the matrix B = U1 U11 U12 . U2 U21 U22 (d) Let C = −U2 U1 . Calculate the product C’HC. 3. Use the Lagrangian multiplier method to find the critical points of f (x, y) = x + y subject to x2 + y 2 = 2. Then use the bordered Hessian to determine which point is a maximum and which is a minimum. (There are two critical points.) 4. Determine whether f (x, y) = xy is concave, convex, quasiconcave, or quasiconvex. (x > 0 and y > 0.) 5. Let U(x, y), U, x, y > 0, be a homogenous of degree 1 and concave function with Uxy = 0. (a) Show that V (x, y) = [U(x, y)]a is strictly concave if 0 < a < 1 and V (x, y) is strictly quasi-concave for all a > 0. Hint: Uxx Uyy = [Uxy ]2 . (b) Show that F (x, y) = xβ + y β , x, y > 0 and −∞ < β < 1 is homogenous of degree 1 and concave if a = 1. (c) Determine the range of a so that F (x, y) is strictly concave. (d) Determine the range of a so that F (x, y) is strictly quasi-concave. a/β 81 9.8 Nonlinear Programming The general nonlinear programming problem is: g 1 (x1 , . . . , xn ) ≤ b1 . . . max F (x1 , . . . , xn ) subject to x1 ,...,xn g m (x1 , . . . , xn ) ≤ bm x1 , . . . , xn ≥ 0. In equality constraint problems, the number of constraints should be less than the number of policy variables, m < n. For nonlinear programming problems, there is no such a restriction, m can be greater than or equal to n. In vector notation, max F (x) x subject to g(x) ≤ b, x ≥ 0. 9.9 Kuhn-Tucker condition Define the Lagrangian function as m L(x, y) = F (x) + y(b − g(x)) = F (x1 , . . . , xn ) + j=1 yj (bj − g j (x1 , . . . , xn )). Kuhn-Tucker condition: The FOC is given by the Kuhn-Tucker conditions: ∂L ∂F = − ∂xi ∂xi ∂g j yj ≤ 0, ∂xi j=1 yj m xi ∂L = 0 xi ≥ 0, ∂xi i = 1, . . . , n ∂L = bj − g j (x) ≥ 0, ∂yj ∂L = 0 yj ≥ 0, j = 1, . . . , m ∂yj Kuhn Tucker theorem: x∗ solves the nonlinear programming problem if (x∗ , y ∗) solves the saddle point problem: L(x, y ∗ ) ≤ L(x∗ , y ∗) ≤ L(x∗ , y) for all x ≥ 0, y ≥ 0, Conversely, suppose that f (x) is a concave function and g j (x) are convex functions (concave programming) and the constraints satisfy the constraint qualification condition that there is some point in the opportunity set which satisfies all the inequality constraints as strict inequalities, i.e., there exists a vector x0 ≥ 0 such that g j (x0 ) < bj , j = 1, . . . , m, then x∗ solves the nonlinear programming problem only if there is a y ∗ for which (x∗ , y ∗ ) solves the saddle point problem. If constraint qualification is not satisfied, it is possible that a solution does not satisfy the K-T condition. If it is satisfied, then the K-T condition will be necessary. For the case of concave programming, it is also sufficient. 82 In economics applications, however, it is not convenient to use K-T condition to find the solution. In stead, we first solve the equality constraint version of the problem and then use K-T condition to check or modify the solution when some constraints are violated. The K-T condition for minimization problems: the inequalities reversed. 9.10 Examples Example 1. (Joint product profit maximization) The cost function of a competitive producer producing 2 joint products is c(x1 , x2 ) = x2 + x1 x2 + x2 . The profit function 1 2 is given by π(p1 , p2 ) = p1 x1 + p2 x2 − (x2 + x1 x2 + x2 ). 1 2 x1 ≥0,x2 ≥0 max f (x1 , x2 ) = p1 x1 + p2 x2 − (x2 + x1 x2 − x2 ) 1 2 K-T condition: f1 = p1 − 2x1 − x2 ≤ 0, f2 = p2 − x1 − 2x2 ≤ 0, xi fi = 0, i = 1, 2. Case 1. p1 /2 < p2 < 2p1 . x1 = (2p1 − p2 )/3, x2 = (2p2 − p1 )/3. Case 2. 2p1 < p2 . x1 = 0, x2 = p2 /2. Case 3. 2p2 < p1 . x1 = p1 /2, x2 = 0. Example 2. The production function of a producer is given by q = (x1 +1)(x2 +1)−1. For q = 8, calculate the cost function c(w1 , w2 ). x1 ≥0,x2 ≥0 min w1 x1 + w2 x2 subject to − [(x1 + 1)(x2 + 1) − 1] ≥ −8 Lagrangian function: L = w1 x1 + w1 x2 + λ[(x1 + 1)(x2 + 1) − 9]. K-T conditions: L1 = w1 − λ(x2 − 1) ≥ 0, L2 = w2 − λ(x2 − 1) ≥ 0, xi Li = 0, i = 1, 2, and Lλ = (x1 + 1)(x2 + 1) − 9 ≥ 0, λLλ = 0. Case 1. w1 /9 < w2 < 9w1 . √ x1 = 9w2 /w1 − 1, x2 = 9w1 /w2 − 1 and c(w1 , w2 ) = 6 w1 w2 − w1 − w2 . Case 2. 9w1 < w2 . x1 = 8, x2 = 0, and c(w1 , w2 ) = 8w1 . Case 3. 9w2 < w1 . x1 = 0, x2 = 8, c(w1 , w2 ) = 8w2 . 83 Example 3. The utility function of a consumer is U(x1 , x2 ) = x1 (x2 +1). The market price is p1 = p2 = 1 and the consumer has $11. Therefore the budget constraint is x1 + x2 ≤ 11. Suppose that both products are under rationing. Besides the money price, the consumer has to pay ρi rationing points for each unit of product i consumed. Assume that ρ1 = 1 and ρ2 = 2 and the consumer has q rationing points. The rationing point constraint is x1 + 2x2 ≤ q. The utility maximization problem is given by max U(x1 , x2 ) = x1 (x2 + 1) x1 ,x2 subject to x1 + x2 ≤ 11, x1 + 2x2 ≤ q, x1 , x2 ≥ 0. Lagrangian function: L = x1 (x2 + 1) + λ1 (11 − x1 − x2 ) + λ2 (q − x1 − 2x2 ). K-T conditions: L1 = x2 + 1 − λ1 − λ2 ≤ 0, L2 = x1 − λ1 − 2λ2 ≤ 0, xi Li = 0, i = 1, 2, and Lλ1 = 11 − x1 − x2 ≥ 0, Lλ2 = q − x1 − 2x2 ≥ 0 λi Lλi = 0. Case 1: q < 2. x1 = q, x2 = 0, λ1 = 0, and λ2 = 1. Case 2: 2 ≤ q ≤ 14. x1 = (q + 2)/2, x2 = (q − 2)/4, λ1 = 0, and λ2 = (q + 2)/4. Case 3: 14 < q ≤ 16. x1 = 22 − q, x2 = q − 11, λ1 = 3(q − 14), and λ2 = 2(16 − q). Case 4: 16 < q. x1 = 6, x2 = 5, λ1 = 6, and λ2 = 0. 9.11 Problems √ 1. Given the individual utility function U(X, Y ) = 2 X + Y , a) show that U is quasi-concave for X ≥ 0 and Y ≥ 0, b) state the Kuhn-Tucker conditions of the following problem: √ max 2 X + Y X≥0, Y ≥0 s. t. PX X + PY Y ≤ I, Y c) derive the demand functions X(PX , PY , I) and Y (PX , PY , I) for the case I ≥ PX , check that the K-T conditions are satisfied, 2 PY d) and do the same for I < PX . e) Given that I = 1 and PY = 1, derive the ordinary demand function X = D(PX ). f) Are your answers in (c) and (d) global maximum? Unique global maximum? Why P2 84 or why not? 2. A farm has a total amount of agricultural land of one acre. It can produce two crops, √ (C) and lettuce (L), according to the production functions C = NC and corn L = 2 NL respectively, where NC (NL ) is land used in corn (lettuce) production. The prices of corn and lettuce are p and q respectively. Thus, if the farm uses NC of land in corn production and NL in lettuce production, (NC ≥ 0, NL ≥ 0, and √ NC + NL ≤ 1) its total revenue is pNC + 2q NL . a) Suppose the farm is interested in maximizing its revenue. State the revenue maximization problem and the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. b) Given that q > p > 0, how much of each output will the farm produce? Check that the K-T conditions are satisfied. c) Given that p ≥ q > 0, do the same as (b). 3. Suppose that a firm has two activities producing two goods “meat” (M) and “egg” (E) from the same input “chicken” (C) according to the production functions 1/2 M = CM and E = CE , where CM (respectively CE ) ≥ 0 is the q. Suppose in the ¯ short run, the firm has C units of chicken that it must take as given and suppose that the firm faces prices p > 0, q > 0 of meat and egg respectively. 0.5 a) Show that the profit function π = pCM + qCE is quasi-concave in (CM , CE ). b) Write down the short run profit maximization problem. c) State the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. d) Derive the short run supply functions. (There are two cases.) e) Is your solution a global maximum? Explain. 4. State the Kuhn-Tucker conditions of the following nonlinear programming problem max s. t. U(X, Y ) = 3 ln X + ln Y 2X + Y ≤ 24 X + 2Y ≤ 24 X ≥ 0, Y ≥ 0. Show that X = 9, Y = 6, λ1 = 1/6, and λ2 = 0 satisfy the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. What is the economic interpretations of λ1 = 1/6 and λ2 = 0 if the first constraint is interpreted as the income constraint and the second constraint as the rationing point constraint of a utility maximization problem? 9.12 Linear Programming – A Graphic Approach Example 1 (A Production Problem). A manufacturer produces tables x1 and desks x2 . Each table requires 2.5 hours for assembling (A), 3 hours for buffing (B), and 1 hour for crating (C). Each desks requires 1 hour for assembling (A), 3 hours for buffing (B), and 2 hours for crating (C). The firm can use no more than 20 hours for assembling, 30 hours for buffing, and 16 hours for crating each week. Its profit margin is $3 per table and $4 per desk. 85 max Π subject to 2.5x1 + x2 3x1 + 3x2 x1 + 2x2 x1 , x2 = ≤ ≤ ≤ ≥ 3x1 + 4x2 20 30 16 0. (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) extreme point: The intersection of two constraints. extreme point theorem: If an optimal feasible value of the objective function exists, it will be found at one of the extreme points. In the example, There are 10 extreme points, but only 5 are feasible: (0 ,0), (8, 0), (6 2 , 3 1 ), (4, 6), and (0, 8), called basic feasible solutions. At (4, 6), Π = 36 is the 3 3 optimal. x2 v T v v v v y2 T v d Zd v rZ v rd Z r Z dr v rq Z v dZ (4,6) rr dv rr Z v dZ rr vdZZ rr v d Z rr r v d Z v v v v v E x1 e e de e d e d ed HH e d e HH d e Hd H Hd e H (9,3) e d q HH e d HH e d H H e d H Ey Example 2 (The Diet Problem). A farmer wants to see that her herd gets the minimum daily requirement of three basic nutrients A, B, and C. Daily requirements are 14 for A, 12 for B, and 18 for C. Product y1 has 2 units of A and 1 unit each of B and C; product y2 has 1 unit each of A and B and 3 units of C. The cost of y1 is $2, and the cost of y2 is $4. min c subject to 2y1 + y2 y1 + y2 y1 + 3y2 y1 , y2 = ≥ ≥ ≥ ≥ 2y1 + 4y2 14 12 18 0. (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) 86 Slack and surplus variables: To find basic solutions, equations are needed. This is done by incorporating a separate slack or surplus variable si into each inequality. In example 1, the system becomes 2.5x1 + x2 + s1 = 20 In matrix for, 2.5 1 1 0 0 3 3 0 1 0 1 2 0 0 1 x1 x2 s1 s2 s3 20 = 30 . 16 3x1 + 3x2 + s2 = 30 x1 + 2x2 + s3 = 16. In example 2, the inequalities are ”≥” and the surplus variables are substracted: 2y1 + y2 − s1 = 14 In matrix for, 2 1 −1 0 0 1 1 0 −1 0 1 3 0 0 −1 y1 y2 s1 s2 s3 14 = 12 . 18 y1 + y2 − s2 = 12 y1 + 3y2 − s3 = 18. For a system of m equations and n variables, where n > m, a solution in which at least n − m variables equal to zero is an extreme point. Thus by setting n − mand solving the m equations for the remaining m variables, an extreme point can be found. There are n!/m!(n − m)! such solutions. 9.13 Linear programming – The simplex algorithm The algorithm moves from one basic feasible solution to another, always improving upon the previous solutions, until the optimal solution is reached. In each step, those variables set equal to zero are called not in the basis and those not set equal to zero are called in the basis. Let use example one to illustrate the procedure. 1. The initial Simplex Tableau x1 x2 2.5 1 3 3 1 2 -3 -4 s1 1 0 0 0 s2 0 1 0 0 s3 0 0 1 0 Constant 20 30 16 0 The first basic feasible solution can be read from the tableau as x1 = 0, x2 = 0, s1 = 20, s2 = 30, and s3 = 16. The value of Π is zero. 2. The Pivot Element and a change of Basis 87 (a) The negative indicator with the largest absolute value determines the variable to enter the basis. Here it is x2 . The x2 column is called the pivot column (j-th column). (b) The variable to be eliminated is determined by the smallest displacement ratio. Displacement ratios are found by dividing the elements of the constant column by the elements of the pivot column. Here the smallest is 16/2=8 and row 3 is the pivot row (i-th row). The pivot element is 2. 3. (Pivoting) and we are going to move to the new basic solution with s3 = 0 and x2 > 0. First, divides every element of the pivoting row by the pivoting element (2 in this example) to make the pivoting element equal to 1. Then subtracts akj times the pivoting row from k-th row to make the j-th column a unit vector. (This procedure is called the Gaussian elimination method, usually used in solving simultaneous equations.) After pivoting, the Tableau becomes x1 x2 s1 s2 s3 Constant 2 0 1 0 -.5 12 1.5 0 0 1 -1.5 6 .5 1 0 0 .5 8 -1 0 0 0 2 32 The basic solution is x2 = 8, s1 = 12, s2 = 6, and x1 = s3 = 0. The value of Π is 32. 4. (Optimization) Repeat steps 2-3 until a maximum is reached. In the example, x1 column is the new pivoting column. The second row is the pivoting row and 1.5 is the pivoting element. After pivoting, the tableau becomes x1 x2 s1 s2 s3 Constant 0 0 1 − 4 1.5 4 3 2 1 0 0 -1 4 3 1 0 1 0 −3 1 6 2 0 0 0 1 36 3 The basic solution is x1 = 4, x2 = 6, s1 = 4, and s2 = s3 = 0. The value of Π is 36. Since there is no more negative indicators, the process stops and the basic solution is the optimal. s1 = 4 > 0 and s2 = s3 = 0 means that the first constraint is not binding but the second and third are binding. The indicators for s2 and s3 , t2 = 2 and t3 = 1 are called the shadow values, representing the 3 marginal contributions of increasing one hour for buffing or crating. Because y1 = y2 = 0 is not feasible, the simplex algorithm for minimization problem is more complex. Usually, we solve its dual problem. 88 9.14 Linear programming – The dual problem To every linear programming problem there corresponds a dual problem. If the original problem, called the primal problem, is max F = cx x subject to Ax ≤ b, x≥0 then the dual problem is min G = yb y subject to yA ≥ c, y≥0 where a11 . . . a1n . . , .. . A= . . . . am1 . . . amn Existence theorem: A necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of a solution is that the opportunity sets of both the primal and dual problems are nonempty. Proof: Suppose x, y are feasible. Then Ax ≤ b, yA ≥ c. It follows that F (x) = cx ≤ yAx and G(y) = yb ≥ yAx. Therefore, F (x) ≤ G(y). Duality theorem: A necessary and sufficient condition for a feasible vector to represent a solution is that there exists a feasible vector for the dual problem for which the values of the objective functions of both problems are equal. Complementary slackness theorem: A necessary and sufficient condition for feasible vectors x∗ , y ∗ to solve the dual problems is that they satisfy the complementary slackness condition: (c − y ∗ A)x∗ = 0 Proof: Use Kuhn-Tucker theorem. Dual of the Diet Problem max c∗ subject to 2x1 + x2 + x1 x1 + x2 + 3x3 x1 , x2 , x3 = ≤ ≤ ≥ 14x1 + 12x2 + 18x3 2 4 0. (14) (15) (16) (17) y ∗(b − Ax∗ ) = 0. x1 . x = . , . xn b1 . b = . , . bm c = (c1 , . . . , cn ), y = (y1 , . . . , ym ). x1 , x2 , x3 , is interpreted as the imputed value of nutrient A, B, C, respectively. 89 10 10.1 General Equilibrium and Game Theory Utility maximization and demand function A consumer wants to maximize his utility function subject to his budget constraint: max U(x1 , . . . , xn ) subj. to p1 x1 + · · · + pn xn = I. Endogenous variables: x1 , . . . , xn Exogenous variables: p1 , . . . , pn , I (the consumer is a price taker) Solution is the demand functions xk = Dk (p1 , . . . , pn , I), k = 1, . . . , n Example: max U(x1 , x2 ) = a ln x1 + b ln x2 subject to p1 x1 + p2 x2 = m. L = a ln x1 + b ln x2 + λ(m − p1 x1 − p2 x2 ). a b FOC: L1 = − λp1 = 0, L2 = − λp2 = 0 and Lλ = m − p1 x1 − p2 x2 = 0. x1 x2 p1 am bm a x2 = ⇒ x1 = , x2 = ⇒ b x1 p2 (a + b)p1 (a + b)p2 0 −p1 −p2 −a ap2 bp2 0 −p1 SOC: = 22 + 21 > 0. x2 1 x1 x2 −b −p2 0 x2 2 am bm ⇒ x1 = , x2 = is a local maximum. (a + b)p1 (a + b)p2 10.2 Profit maximization and supply function A producer’s production technology can be represented by a production function q = f (x1 , . . . , xn ). Given the prices, the producer maximizes his profits: max Π(x1 , . . . , xn ; p, p1 , . . . , pn ) = pf (x1 , . . . , xn ) − p1 x1 − · · · − pn xn Exogenous variables: p, p1 , . . . , pn (the producer is a price taker) Solution is the supply function q = S(p, p1 , . . . , pn ) and the input demand functions, xk = Xk (p, p1 , . . . , pn ) k = 1, . . . , n √ √ √ √ Example: q = f (x1 , x2 ) = 2 x1 + 2 x2 and Π(x1 , x2 ; p, p1 , p2 ) = p(2 x1 + 2 x2 ) − p1 x1 − p2 x2 , √ √ max p(2 x1 + 2 x2 ) − p1 x1 − p2 x2 x1 .x2 FOC: ∂Π p ∂Π p = √ − p1 = 0 and = √ − p2 = 0. ∂x1 x1 ∂x2 x2 ⇒ x1 = (p/p1 )2 , x2 = (p/p2 )2 (input demand functions) and q = 2(p/p1 ) + 2(p/p2 ) = 2p( p11 + p12 ) (the supply function) 90 Π = p2 ( p11 + SOC: 1 ) p2 is negative definite. 10.3 ∂2Π ∂x2 1 ∂2Π ∂x1 ∂x2 −p ∂2Π ∂x1 ∂x2 2x3/2 = 1 ∂2Π 0 ∂x2 1 0 2x2 3/2 −p Transformation function and profit maximization In more general cases, the technology of a producer is represented by a transformation j j j j j function: F j (y1 , . . . , yn ) = 0, where (y1 , . . . , yn ) is called a production plan, if yk > 0 j (yk ) then k is an output (input) of j. Example: a producer produces two outputs, y1 and y2 , using one input y3 . Its technology is given by the transformation function (y1 )2 + (y2 )2 + y3 = 0. Its profit is Π = p1 y1 + p2 y2 + p3 y3 . The maximization problem is y1 ,y2 ,y3 max p1 y1 + p2 y2 + p3 y3 subject to (y1 )2 + (y2 )2 + y3 = 0. To solve the maximization problem, we can eliminate y3 : x = −y3 = (y1 )2 + (y2 )2 > 0 and max p1 y1 + p2 y2 − p3 [(y1 )2 + (y2 )2 ]. y1 ,y2 The solution is: y1 = p1 /(2p3 ), y2 = p2 /(2p3 ) (the supply functions of y1 and y2 ), and x = −y3 = [p1 /(2p3 )]2 + [p2 /(2p3 )]2 (the input demand function for y3 ). 10.4 The concept of an abstract economy and a competitive equilibrium Commodity space: Assume that there are n commodities. The commodity space is n R+ = {(x1 , . . . , xn ); xk ≥ 0} Economy: There are I consumers, J producers, with initial endowments of commodities ω = (ω1 , . . . , ωn ). i Consumer i has a utility function U i (x1 , . . . , xi ), i = 1, . . . , I. n j j Producer j has a production transformation function F j (y1 , . . . , yn ) = 0, A price system: (p1 , . . . , pn ). A private ownership economy: Endowments and firms (producers) are owned by consumers. i i Consumer i’s endowment is ω i = (ω1 , . . . , ωn ), I ω i = ω. i=1 I Consumer i’s share of firm j is θij ≥ 0, i=1 θij = 1. j j An allocation: xi = (xi , . . . , xi ), i = 1, . . . , I, and y j = (y1 , . . . , yn ), j = 1, . . . , J. 1 n 91 A competitive equilibrium: A combination of a price system p = (¯1 , . . . , pn ) and an allocation ({¯i }i=1,...,I , {¯j }j=1,...,J ) ¯ p ¯ x y such that 1. i xi = ω + j y j (feasibility condition). ¯ ¯ j j 2. y maximizes Π , j = 1, . . . , J and xi maximizes U i , subject to i’s budget con¯ ¯ i i 1 i straint p1 x1 + . . . + pn xn = p1 ω1 + . . . + pn ωn + θi1 Π1 + . . . + θiJ ΠJ . Existence Theorem: Suppose that the utility functions are all quasi-concave and the production transformation functions satisfy some theoretic conditions, then a competitive equilibrium exists. Welfare Theorems: A competitive equilibrium is efficient and an efficient allocation can be achieved as a competitive equilibrium through certain income transfers. Constant returns to scale economies and non-substitution theorem: Suppose there is only one nonproduced input, this input is indispensable to production, there is no joint production, and the production functions exhibits constant returns to scale. Then the competitive equilibrium price system is determined by the production side only. 92 10.5 Multi-person Decision Problem and Game Theory In this chapter, we consider the situation when there are n > 1 persons with different objective (utility) functions; that is, different persons have different preferences over possible outcomes. There are two cases: 1. Game theory: The outcome depends on the behavior of all the persons involved. Each person has some control over the outcome; that is, each person controls certain strategic variables. Each one’s utility depends on the decisions of all persons. We want to study how persons make decisions. 2. Public Choice: Persons have to make decision collectively, eg., by voting. We consider only game theory here. Game theory: the study of conflict and cooperation between persons with different objective functions. Example (a 3-person game): The accuracy of shooting of A, B, C is 1/3, 2/3, 1, respectively. Each person wants to kill the other two to become the only survivor. They shoot in turn starting A. Question: What is the best strategy for A? 10.6 Ingredients and classifications of games A game is a collection of rules known to all players which determine what players may do and the outcomes and payoffs resulting from their choices. The ingredients of a game: 1. Players: Persons having some influences upon possible income (decision makers). 2. Moves: decision points in the game at which players must make choices between alternatives (personal moves) and randomization points (called nature’s moves). 3. A play: A complete record of the choices made at moves by the players and realizations of randomization. 4. Outcomes and payoffs: a play results in an outcome, which in turn determines the rewords to players. Classifications of games: 1. according to number of players: 2-person games – conflict and cooperation possibilities. n-person games – coalition formation possibilities in addition. infinite-players’ games – corresponding to perfect competition in economics. 2. according to number of strategies: finite – strategy (matrix) games, each person has a finite number of strategies, 93 payoff functions can be represented by matrices. infinite – strategy (continuous or discontinuous payoff functions) games like duopoly games. 3. according to sum of payoffs: 0-sum games – conflict is unavoidable. non-zero sum games – possibilities for cooperation. 4. according to preplay negotiation possibility: non-cooperative games – each person makes unilateral decisions. cooperative games – players form coalitions and decide the redistribution of aggregate payoffs. 10.7 The extensive form and normal form of a game Extensive form: The rules of a game can be represented by a game tree. The ingredients of a game tree are: 1. Players 2. Nodes: they are players’ decision points (personal moves) and randomization points (nature’s moves). 3. Information sets of player i: each player’s decision points are partitioned into information sets. An information set consists of decision points that player i can not distinguish when making decisions. 4. Arcs (choices): Every point in an information set should have the same number of choices. 5. Randomization probabilities (of arcs following each randomization points). 6. Outcomes (end points) 7. Payoffs: The gains to players assigned to each outcome. A pure strategy of player i: An instruction that assigns a choice for each information set of player i. Total number of pure strategies of player i: the product of the numbers of choices of all information sets of player i. Once we identify the pure strategy set of each player, we can represent the game in normal form (also called strategic form). 1. Strategy sets for each player: S1 = {s1 , . . . , sm }, S2 = {σ1 , . . . , σn }. 2. Payoff matrices: π1 (si , σj ) = aij , π2 (si , σj ) = bij . A = [aij ], B = [bij ]. Normal form: d II d d I s1 . . . σ1 (a11 , b11 ) . . . (am1 , bm1 ) ... ... .. . σn (a1n , b1n ) . . . sm . . . (amn , bmn ) 94 10.8 Examples Example 1: A perfect information game 1 L R 2 2 d r l L d R d d 1 9 9 6 3 7 8 2 d II d Example 2: Prisoners’ dilemma game 1 R L ¨ 2 © L dd L dd R R 4 4 0 5 5 0 1 1 S1 = { L, R }, S2 = { Ll, Lr, Rl, Rr }. I d Ll Lr Rl Rr L (1,9) (9,6) (1,9) (9,6) R (3,7)* (8,2) (3,7) (8,2) d II d d S1 = { L, R }, S2 = { L, R }. Example 3: Hijack game 1 R L 2 L d R d −1 2 2 −10 −2 −10 S1 = { L, R }, S2 = { L, R }. 1/2 ¨rr1/2 ¨ rr 1 1¨¨ e R ¡d r L l e ¡ ¨d 2 ¡e ¡e © d L¡ e R L¡ e R 4 I L R L R (4,4) (0,5) (5,0) (1,1)* d II d d I L R L R (-1,2) (-1,2)* (2,-2)* (-10,-10) Example 4: A simplified stock price manipulation game 0 d II d I d 2 7 5 5 7 4 5 4 2 3 7 S1 = { Ll, Lr, Rl, Rr }, S2 = { L, R }. Ll Lr Rl Rr L R (4, 3.5) (4, 2) (3.5, 4.5) (3.5, 4.5) (5.5, 5)* (4.5, 4.5) (5,6) (4,7) Remark: Each extensive form game corresponds a normal form game. However, different extensive form games may have the same normal form. 95 10.9 Strategy pair and pure strategy Nash equilibrium 1. A Strategy Pair: (si , σj ). Given a strategy pair, there corresponds a payoff pair (aij , bij ). 2. A Nash equilibrium: A strategy pair (si∗ , σj∗) such that ai∗j∗ ≥ aij∗ and bi∗j∗ ≥ bi∗j for all (i, j). Therefore, there is no incentives for each player to deviate from the equilibrium strategy. ai∗j∗ and bi∗j∗ are called the equilibrium payoff. The equilibrium payoffs of the examples are marked each with a star in the normal form. Remark 1: It is possible that a game does no have a pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Also, a game can have more than one Nash equilibria. Remark 2: Notice that the concept of a Nash equilibrium is defined for a normal form game. For a game in extensive form (a game tree), we have to find the normal form before we can find the Nash equilibria. 10.10 Subgames and subgame perfect Nash equilibria 1. Subgame: A subgame in a game tree is a part of the tree consisting of all the nodes and arcs following a node that form a game by itself. 2. Within an extensive form game, we can identify some subgames. 3. Also, each pure strategy of a player induces a pure strategy for every subgame. 4. Subgame perfect Nash equilibrium: A Nash equilibrium is called subgame perfect if it induces a Nash equilibrium strategy pair for every subgame. 5. Backward induction: To find a subgame perfect equilibrium, usually we work backward. We find Nash equilibria for lowest level (smallest) subgames and replace the subgames by its Nash equilibrium payoffs. In this way, the size of the game is reduced step by step until we end up with the equilibrium payoffs. All the equilibria, except the equilibrium strategy pair (L,R) in the hijack game, are subgame perfect. Remark: The concept of a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is defined only for an extensive form game. 10.10.1 Perfect information game and Zemelo’s Theorem An extensive form game is called perfect information if every information set consists only one node. Every perfect information game has a pure strategy subgame perfect Nash Equilibrium. 96 10.10.2 Perfect recall game and Kuhn’s Theorem A local strategy at an information set u ∈ Ui : A probability distribution over the choice set at Uij . A behavior strategy: A function which assigns a local strategy for each u ∈ Ui . The set of behavior strategies is a subset of the set of mixed strategies. Kuhn’s Theorem: In every extensive game with perfect recall, a strategically equivalent behavior strategy can be found for every mixed strategy. However, in a non-perfect recall game, a mixed strategy may do better than behavior strategies because in a behavior strategy the local strategies are independent whereas they can be correlated in a mixed strategy. ¨rr A 2-person 0-sum non-perfect recall game. 1/2 ¨ rr 1/2 ¨ ¨ 1 1 1 1 rr u¨¨ 2 11 NE is (µ∗ , µ∗ ) = ( ac ⊕ bd, A ⊕ B). 1 2 2 2 2 2 a d b A dd B µ∗ is not a behavioral strategy. d 1 ¨ d d u12 © d d 1 −1 d d c d c d d d −1 1 ¡e ¡e ¡e 0 ¡ e −2 0¡ e ¡ e2 e ¡ e ¡ e ¡ −2 0 2 0 0 10.10.3 Reduction of a game Redundant strategy: A pure strategy is redundant if it is strategically identical to another strategy. Reduced normal form: The normal form without redundant strategies. Equivalent normal form: Two normal forms are equivalent if they have the same reduced normal form. Equivalent extensive form: Two extensive forms are equivalent if their normal forms are equivalent. 10.11 Continuous games and the duopoly game In many applications, S1 and S2 are infinite subsets of Rm and Rn Player 1 controls m variables and player 2 controls n variables (however, each player has infinite many strtategies). The normal form of a game is represented by two functions Π1 = Π1 (x; y) and Π2 = Π2 (x; y), where x ∈ S1 ⊂ Rm and y ∈ S2 ⊂ Rn . To simplify the presentation, assume that m = n = 1. A strategic pair is (x, y) ∈ S1 × S2 . A Nash equilibrium is a pair (x∗ , y ∗) such that Π1 (x∗ , y ∗ ) ≥ Π1 (x, y ∗ ) and Π2 (x∗ , y ∗) ≥ Π2 (x∗ , y) for all x ∈ S1 y ∈ S2 . 97 Consider the case when Πi are continuously differentiable and Π1 is strictly concave in x and Π2 strictly concave in y (so that we do not have to worry about the SOC’s). Reaction functions and Nash equilibrium: To player 1, x is his endogenous variable and y is his exogenous variable. For each y chosen by player 2, player 1 will choose a x ∈ S1 to maximize his objective function Π1 . This relationship defines a behavioral equation x = R1 (y) which can be obtained by solving the FOC for player 1, Π1 (x; y) = 0. Similarly, player 2 regards y as enx dogenous and x exogenous and wants to maximize Π2 for a given x chosen by player 1. Player 2’s reaction function (behavioral equation) y = R2 (x) is obtained by solving 2 Πy (x; y) = 0. A Nash equilibrium is an intersection of the two reaction functions. The FOC for a Nash equilibrium is given by Π1 (x∗ ; y ∗ ) = 0 and Π2 (x∗ ; y ∗) = 0. x y Duopoly game: There are two sellers (firm 1 and firm 2) of a product. The (inverse) market demand function is P = a − Q. The marginal production costs are c1 and c2 , respectively. Assume that each firm regards the other firm’s output as given (not affected by his output quantity). The situation defines a 2-person game as follows: Each firm i controls his own output quantity qi . (q1 , q2 ) together determine the market price P = a − (q1 + q2 ) which in turn determines the profit of each firm: Π1 (q1 , q2 ) = (P −c1 )q1 = (a−c1 −q1 −q2 )q1 and Π2 (q1 , q2 ) = (P −c2 )q2 = (a−c2 −q1 −q2 )q2 The FOC are ∂Π1 /∂q1 = a − c1 − q2 − 2q1 = 0 and ∂Π2 /∂q2 = a − c2 − q1 − 2q2 = 0. The reaction functions are q1 = 0.5(a − c1 − q2 ) and q2 = 0.5(a − c2 − q1 ). ∗ ∗ The Cournot Nash equilibrium is (q1 , q2 ) = ((a − 2c1 + c2 )/3, (a − 2c2 + c1 )/3) with P ∗ = (a + c1 + c2 )/3. (We have to assume that a − 2c1 + c2 , a − 2c2 + c1 ≥ 0.) 10.11.1 A simple bargaining model Two players, John and Paul, have $ 1 to divide between them. They agree to spend at most two days negotiating over the division. The first day, John will make an offer, Paul either accepts or comes back with a counteroffer the second day. If they cannot reach an agreement in two days, both players get zero. John (Paul) discounts payoffs in the future at a rate of α (β) per day. A subgame perfect equilibrium of this bargaining game can be derived using backward induction. 1. On the second day, John would accept any non-negative counteroffer made by Paul. Therefore, Paul would make proposal of getting the whole $ 1 himself and John would get $ 0. 2. On the first day, John should make an offer such that Paul gets an amount equivalent to getting $ 1 the second day, otherwise Paul will reject the offer. Therefore, John will propose of 1 − β for himself and β for Paul and Paul will accept the offer. 98 An example of a subgame non-perfect Nash equilibrium is that John proposes of getting 1-0.5β for himself and 0.5β for Paul and refuses to accept any counteroffer made by Paul. In this equilibrium, Paul is threatened by John’s incredible threat and accepts only one half of what he should have had in a perfect equilibrium. 10.12 2-person 0-sum game 1. B = −A so that aij + bij = 0. 2. Maxmin strategy: If player 1 plays si , then the minimum he will have is minj aij , called the security level of strategy si . A possible guideline for player 1 is to choose a strategy such that the security level is maximized: Player 1 chooses si∗ so that minj ai∗j ≥ minj aij for all i. Similarly, since bij = −aij , Player 2 chooses σj ∗ so that maxi aij∗ ≤ maxi aij for all j. 3. Saddle point: If ai∗j∗ = maxi minj aij = minj maxi aij , then (si∗ , σj∗ ) is called a saddle point. If a saddle point exists, then it is a Nash equilibrium. A1 = 2 1 4 −1 0 6 A2 = 1 0 0 1 In example A1 , maxi minj aij = minj maxi aij = 1 (s1 , σ2 ) is a saddle point and hence a Nash equilibrium. In A2 , maxi minj aij = 0 = minj maxi aij = 1 and no saddle point exists. If there is no saddle points, then there is no pure strategy equilibrium. 4. Mixed strategy for player i: A probability distribution over Si . p = (p1 , . . . , pm ), q = (q1 , . . . , qn )′ . (p, q) is a mixed strategy pair. Given (p, q), the expected payoff of player 1 is pAq. A mixed strategy Nash equilibrium (p∗ , q ∗ ) is such that p∗ Aq ∗ ≥ pAq ∗ and p∗ Aq ∗ ≤ p∗ Aq for all p and all q. 5. Security level of a mixed strategy: Given player 1’s strategy p, there is a pure strategy of player 2 so that the expected payoff to player 1 is minimized, just as in the case of a pure strategy of player 1. t(p) ≡ min{ j pi ai1 , . . . , i i pi ain }. The problem of finding the maxmin mixed strategy (to find p∗ to maximize t(p)) can be stated as max t subj. to p i pi ai1 ≥ t, . . . , i pi ain ≥ t, pi = 1. i 6. Linear programming problem: The above problem can be transformed into a linear programming problem as follows: (a) Add a positive constant to each element of A to insure that t(p) > 0 for all p. (b) Define yi ≡ pi /t(p) and 99 replace the problem of max t(p) with the problem of min 1/t(p) = constraints become i yi ai1 ≥ 1, . . . , i yi ain ≥ 1. y1 ,...,ym ≥0 i yi . The min y1 + . . . + ym subj. to i yi ai1 ≥ 1, . . . , i yi ain ≥ 1 7. Duality: It turns out that player 2’s minmax problem can be transformed similarly and becomes the dual of player 1’s linear programming problem. The existence of a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium is then proved by using the duality theorem in linear programming. 1 0 . 0 1 To find player 2’s equilibrium mixed strategy, we solve the linear programming problem: x1 ,x2 ≥0 Example (tossing coin game): A = max x1 + x2 subj. to x1 ≤ 1 x2 ≤ 1. The solution is x1 = x2 = 1 and therefore the equilibrium strategy for player 2 is ∗ ∗ q1 = q2 = 0.5. x2 y2 T T d d d dr d d d d d d d dr d d d d 1 1 E x1 1 1 E y1 Player 1’s equilibrium mixed strategy is obtained by solving the dual to the linear programming problem: y1 ,y2 ≥0 min y1 + y2 subj. to y1 ≥ 1 y2 ≥ 1. The solution is p∗ = p∗ = 0.5. 1 2 10.13 Mixed strategy equilibria for non-zero sum games The idea of a mixed strategy equilibrium is also applicable to a non-zero sum game. Similar to the simplex algorism for the 0-sum games, there is a Lemke algorism. Example (Game of Chicken) 100 1 N S ¨ 2 © S dd S dd N N 0 0 −3 3 3 −3 −9 −9 d II d I d Swerve Don’t Swerve (0,0) (3,-3)* Don’t (-3,3)* (-9,-9) S1 = { S, N }, S2 = { S, N }. There are two pure strategy NE: (S, N) and (N, S). There is also a mixed strategy NE. Suppose player 2 plays a mixed strategy (q, 1 − q). If player 1 plays S, his expected payoff is Π1 (S) = 0q + (−3)(1 − q). If he plays N, his expected payoff is Π1 (N) = 3q + (−9)(1 − q). For a mixed strategy NE, Π1 (S) = Π1 (N), therefore, q = 2 . 3 ∗ ∗ The mixed strategy is symmetrical: (p∗ , p∗ ) = (q1 , q2 ) = ( 2 , 1 ). 1 2 3 3 Example (Battle of sex Game) 1 O B ¨ 2 © B dd B dd O O 5 4 0 0 0 0 4 5 d II d I d Ball game Opera Ball game (5,4)* (0,0) Opera (0,0) (4,5)* S1 = { B, O }, S2 = { B, O }. There are two pure strategy NE: (B, B) and (O, O). There is also a mixed strategy NE. Suppose player 2 plays a mixed strategy (q, 1 − q). If player 1 plays B, his expected payoff is Π1 (B) = 5q + (0)(1 − q). If he plays O, his expected payoff is Π1 (O) = 0q +(4)(1−q). For a mixed strategy NE, Π1 (B) = Π1 (O), 4 therefore, q = 9 . 4 ∗ ∗ The mixed strategy is: (p∗ , p∗ ) = ( 5 , 9 ) and (q1 , q2 ) = ( 4 , 5 ). 1 2 9 9 9 10.14 Cooperative Game and Characteristic form 2-person 0-sum games are strictly competitive. If player 1 gains $ 1, player 2 will loss $ 1 and therefore no cooperation is possible. For other games, usually some cooperation is possible. The concept of a Nash equilibrium is defined for the situation when no explicit cooperation is allowed. In general, a Nash equilibrium is not efficient (not Pareto optimal). When binding agreements on strategies chosen can be contracted before the play of the game and transfers of payoffs among players after a play of the game is possible, players will negotiate to coordinate their strategies and redistribute the payoffs to achieve better results. In such a situation, the determination of strategies is not the key issue. The problem becomes the formation of coalitions and the distribution of payoffs. 101 Characteristic form of a game: The player set: N = {1, 2, . . . , n}. A coalition is a subset of N: S ⊂ N. A characteristic function v specifies the maximum total payoff of each coalition. Consider the case of a 3-person game. There are 8 subsets of N = {1, 2, 3}, namely, φ, (1), (2), (3), (12), (13), (23), (123). Therefore, a characteristic form game is determined by 8 values v(φ), v(1), v(2), v(3), v(12), v(13), v(2 Super-additivity: If A ∩ B = φ, then v(A ∪ B) ≥ v(A) + v(B). An imputation is a payoff distribution (x1 , x2 , x3 ). Individual rationality: xi ≥ v(i). Group rationality: i∈S xi ≥ v(S). Core C: the set of imputations that satisfy individual rationality and group rationality for all S. Marginal contribution of player i in a coalition S ∪ i: v(S ∪ i) − v(S) Shapley value of player i is an weighted average of all marginal contributions |S|!(n − |S| − 1)! [v(S ∪ i) − v(S)]. n! πi = S⊂N Example: v(φ) = v(1) = v(2) = v(3) = 0, v(12) = v(13) = v(23) = 0.5, v(123) = 1. C = {(x1 , x2 , x3 ), xi ≥ 0, xi + xj ≥ 0.5, x1 + x2 + x3 = 1}. Both (0.3, 0.3, 0.4) and (0.2, 0.4, 0.4) are in C. The Shapley values are (π1 , π2 , π3 ) = ( 1 , 1 , 1 ). 3 3 3 Remark 1: The core of a game can be empty. However, the Shapley values are uniquely determined. Remark 2: Another related concept is the von-Neumann Morgenstern solution. See CH 6 of Intriligator’s Mathematical Optimization and Economic Theory for the motivations of these concepts. 10.15 The Nash bargaining solution for a nontransferable 2-person cooperative game In a nontransferable cooperative game, after-play redistributions of payoffs are impossible and therefore the concepts of core and Shapley values are not suitable. For the case of 2-person games, the concept of Nash bargaining solutions are useful. Let F ⊂ R2 be the feasible set of payoffs if the two players can reach an agreement and Ti the payoff of player i if the negotiation breaks down. Ti is called the threat point of player i. The Nash bargaining solution (x∗ , x∗ ) is defined to be the solution 1 2 to the following problem: 102 x2 T (x1 ,x2 )∈F max (x1 − T1 )(x2 − T2 ) x∗ 2 T2 T1 x∗ 1 E x1 See CH 6 of Intriligator’s book for the motivations of the solution concept. 10.16 Problems two-person 0-sum game: σ1 σ2 σ3 4 3 -2 3 4 10 7 6 8 1. Consider the following I \ II s1 s2 s3 (a) Find the max min strategy of player I smax min and the min max strategy of player II σmin max . (b) Is the strategy pair (smax min , σmin max ) a Nash equilibrium of the game? (c) What are the equilibrium payoffs? 2. Find the maxmin strategy (smax min ) and the minmax strategy (σmin max ) of the following two-person 0-sum game: I \ II σ1 σ2 s1 -3 6 s2 8 -2 s3 6 3 Is the strategy pair (smax min , σmin max ) a Nash equilibrium? If not, use simplex method to find the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. 3. Find the (mixed strategy) Nash Equilibrium of the following two-person game: I \ II H T H (-2, 2) (2, -1) T (2, -2) (-1,2) 4. Suppose that two firms producing a homogenous product face a linear demand curve P = a−bQ = a−b(q1 +q2 ) and that both have the same constant marginal costs c. For a given quantity pair (q1 , q2 ), the profits are Πi = qi (P − c) = qi (a − bq1 − bq2 − c), i = 1, 2. Find the Cournot Nash equilibrium output of each firm. 5. Suppose that in a two-person cooperative game without side payments, if the two players reach an agreement, they can get (Π1 , Π2 ) such that Π2 + Π2 = 47 1 103 and if no agreement is reached, player 1 will get T1 = 3 and player 2 will get T2 = 2. (a) Find the Nash solution of the game. (b) Do the same for the case when side payments are possible. Also answer how the side payments should be done? 6. A singer (player 1), a pianist (player 2), and a drummer (player 3) are offered $ 1,000 to play together by a night club owner. The owner would alternatively pay $ 800 the singer-piano duo, $ 650 the piano drums duo, and $ 300 the piano alone. The night club is not interested in any other combination. Howeover, the singer-drums duo makes $ 500 and the singer alone gets $ 200 a night in a restaurant. The drums alone can make no profit. (a) Write down the characteristic form of the cooperative game with side payments. (b) Find the Shapley values of the game. (c) Characterize the core.Similar Documents
Premium EssayMathematical Economics and Finance
...Mathematical economics and finance: good or bad? Pareto and Walras were the first to use mathematics in economics and finance at the end of the nineteenth century. They created classical models of the free markets and explained these mathematically. After these models were created, other famous economists came up with mathematical economical ideas, such as Schumpeter and Keynes. Mathematics was used to simplify and clarify various complicated theories. This use resulted in both advantages and disadvantages. This essay will evaluate the uncritical use of mathematics in economics and finance on multiple aspects. Firstly, if one uses mathematics in economics and finance uncritically, one needs to know all the numerical values and other variables to actually explain and predict certain events and its mutual interdependencies. This knowledge is never entirely available, because the values depend on too many particular circumstances. What’s more, the succession of events in the history of the economics does not show any internal coherence, which makes predicting harder. Moreover, there is no controlled experiment in the economic research field and no falsifiable hypotheses are made (Von Hayek, 1989). Furthermore, different economic models have different implications, thus are applicable to according situations. Hence, not one mathematical model could be implemented (Rodrik, 2015). In addition, human beings and their behaviour should be included in the theories of economics. This...
Words: 790 - Pages: 4
Free EssayContemporary Approaches
...support better than individual job design programs. Autonomous work groups, quality circles are popular examples of this perspective. Groups are often given resources and responsibilities for areas like safety and quality control and work as a team to identify and correct inefficiencies and work issues. Quantitative Management approach involves the use of mathematical modeling to find the best solutions to problems. This can be applied to a variety of workplace challenges, ranging from making decisions during product development to resolving employee conflicts. It is also known as operations research, and involves a more objective, structured approach to problems or solutions. Many industries can be suited to this management philosophy. One important component of the quantitative management approach is an ability to objectively collect information about a problem and possible solutions to develop appropriate, and useful, mathematical models. This may involve input from several personnel who can present solutions, problems, and issues that may complicate the discussion. The manager can plug all of these data into a mathematical model, which can...
Words: 803 - Pages: 4
Free EssayCalculus
...Calculus is the mathematical study of change,[1] in the same way that geometry is the study of shape and algebra is the study of operations and their application to solving equations. It has two major branches, differential calculus (concerning rates of change and slopes of curves), and integral calculus (concerning accumulation of quantities and the areas under and between curves); these two branches are related to each other by the fundamental theorem of calculus. Both branches make use of the fundamental notions of convergence of infinite sequences and infinite series to a well-defined limit. Generally, modern calculus is considered to have been developed in the 17th century by Isaac Newton and Gottfried Leibniz. Today, calculus has widespread uses in science, engineering and economics and can solve many problems that algebra alone cannot. Calculus is a part of modern mathematics education. A course in calculus is a gateway to other, more advanced courses in mathematics devoted to the study of functions and limits, broadly called mathematical analysis. Calculus has historically been called "the calculus of infinitesimals", or "infinitesimal calculus". The word "calculus" comes from Latin (calculus) and refers to a small stone used for counting. More generally, calculus (plural calculi) refers to any method or system of calculation guided by the symbolic manipulation of expressions. Some examples of other well-known calculi are propositional calculus, calculus of variations...
Words: 561 - Pages: 3
Premium EssayAlways Try Your Best
...How satisfied are you with Wikipedia? Your feedback is important to us! As a token of appreciation for your support you get a chance of winning a Wikipedia T-shirt. Click here to learn more! Calculus From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia Jump to: navigation, search This article is about the branch of mathematics. For other uses, see Calculus (disambiguation). | It has been suggested that Infinitesimal calculus be merged into this article or section. (Discuss) Proposed since May 2011. | Topics in Calculus | Fundamental theorem Limits of functions Continuity Mean value theorem [show]Differential calculus | Derivative Change of variables Implicit differentiation Taylor's theorem Related rates Rules and identities:Power rule, Product rule, Quotient rule, Chain rule | [show]Integral calculus | IntegralLists of integrals Improper integrals Integration by: parts, disks, cylindrical shells, substitution, trigonometric substitution, partial fractions, changing order | [show]Vector calculus | Gradient Divergence Curl Laplacian Gradient theorem Green's theorem Stokes' theorem Divergence theorem | [show]Multivariable calculus | Matrix calculus Partial derivative Multiple integral Line integral Surface integral Volume integral Jacobian | | Calculus (Latin, calculus, a small stone used for counting) is a branch of mathematics focused on limits, functions, derivatives, integrals, and infinite series. This subject constitutes...
Words: 6472 - Pages: 26
Premium EssayEcon60081
...ECON60081 2 hours THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER MATHEMATICAL METHODS FOR ECONOMIC ANALYSIS SAMPLE EXAM Date: Time: Answer ALL Questions in Section A and ALL Questions in Section B. Each Section contributes to 50% of the total marks. Please enter your answers in the Answer Book THIS PAPER MUST NOT BE REMOVED FROM THE EXAMINATION ROOM Electronic calculators may be used provided that they cannot store text. 1 of 3 P.T.O. 2 of 3 ECON60081 SECTION A Answer ALL Questions. Each question carries equal weight. Question 1. Consider the problem Ax = b where ⎛ ⎞ ⎞ ⎛ ⎛ ⎞ 2 1 3 1 1 A = ⎝ 3 2 5 ⎠ x = ⎝ 2 ⎠ b = ⎝ 3 ⎠ 1 1 2 3 2 Determine the degrees of freedom and the number of redundant equations of this system. Further, determine the solution(s) if solutions exists. [10 marks] Question 2. Give formal definitions for the following: (a) a convex function, (b) a strictly con vex set, (c) a differentiable function. Further, give an example of a concave function that is not differentiable. [10 marks] Question 3. Find the solution of the following differential equation = 1 + 3 − 2 ˙ where (0) = 5. [10 marks] Question 4. Find the general solution of the following second order differential equation + 4 + 10 = ¨ ˙ [10 marks] Question 5. Consider the following system of nonlinear difference equations ½ 1+1 = 31 − 2 2 2+1 = 2 + 1 Find the equilibria and classify them as...
Words: 347 - Pages: 2
Premium EssayFinancial Analysis
...------------------------------------------------- Latest version: February 7, 2016 (changes from prior version shown in red) ORF 570 Special Topics in Statistics and Operations Research Course topic: Quantitative Asset Management Transcript title: Special Topics in Statistics and Operations/Quantitative Asset Management Instructor: Frank J. Fabozzi, Ph.D., CFA, Visiting Professor, ORFE Office: 207 in ORFE Building (office shared with Professor Mulvey) Office hours: 4-6pm (this time slot will also be used for presentations on special topics) Classroom: Friend 006 Course description: This course covers asset management focusing on quantitative models applied to equities and bonds (with emphasis on mortgage-backed securities). The quantitative models discussed are asset allocation models and portfolio construction models that include optimization models (mean-variance framework and extensions such as robust portfolio optimization), multi-factor risk models, risk control models, and transaction cost forecasting models. Return attribution models for performance evaluation will be covered. Model risk and model/strategy backtesting will be highlighted. Guest speakers from quantitative asset management firms are scheduled. Determination of final grade: Final exam ………………………………. 40% Design project …………………………… 25% Term paper ………………………………. 25% Problem sets ……………………………… 10% Course material and reading assignments: No textbook is required for the book. Instead...
Words: 4794 - Pages: 20
Free EssayConsumer Theory
...XEQ 201: Calculus II Contents Course description References iv iv Chapter 1. Applications of Differentiation 1.1. Mean value theorems of differential calculus 1.2. Using differentials and derivatives 1.3. Extreme Values iii 1 1 5 7 Course description Application of differentiation. Taylor theorem. Mean Value theorem of differential calculus. Methods of integration. Applications of integration. References 1. Calculus: A complete course by Robert A. Adams and Christopher Essex. 2. Fundamental methods of mathematical economics by Alpha C. Chiang. 3. Schaum’s outline series: Introduction to mathematical economics by Edward T. Dowling iv CHAPTER 1 Applications of Differentiation 1.1. Mean value theorems of differential calculus Theorem 1.1.1 (Mean Value Theorem). Suppose that the function f is continuous on the closed finite interval [a, b] and that it is differentiable on the interval (a, b). Then ∃ a point c ∈ (a, b) such that f (b) − f (a) = f (c) . b−a It means that the slope of the chord joining the points (a, f (a)) and (b, f (b)) is equal to the slope of the tangent line to te curve y = f (x) at the point (c, f (c)) so that the two lines are parallel. Fig 2.28 Example 1.1.1. √ Verify the conclusion of the mean value theorem for f (x) = x on the interval [a, b], where a ≤ x ≤ b. Solution. We are to show that ∃ c ∈ (a, b) such that f (b) − f (a) = f (c) b−a 1 XEQ 201 so long as f is continuous on [a, b] and is...
Words: 2582 - Pages: 11
Free EssayManagerial Accounting
...modelling, corporate finance, leasing and credit analysis on an in-house and public basis • finance and operating lease structuring as a consultant and lessor Alastair is author of a number of books including three published by FT Prentice Hall: Mastering Financial Modelling, Mastering Risk Modelling and The Financial Director’s Guide to Purchase Leasing. Alastair has a degree in Economics and German from London University together with an MBA and is an associate lecturer of finance with the Open University Business School. Excel a practical guide for business calculations Tools enabling managers to carry out financial calculations have evolved in the last 20 years from tables through calculators to programs on PCs and personal organisers. Today, the majority of those in finance have Excel on their desks and increasingly on their laptops or pocket computers. Mastering Financial Mathematics in Microsoft ® Excel provides a comprehensive set of tools and methods to apply Excel to solving mathematical problems. Alastair Day clearly explains the basic calculations for mathematical finance backed up with simple templates for further use and development, together with numerous examples and exercises. Providing an explanation of key financial formulas and subject areas, the book includes a CD which: • allows you to work step-by-step through...
Words: 2202 - Pages: 9
Premium EssayBusinee
...Preventive Maintenance and Replacement Scheduling: Models and Algorithms By Kamran S. Moghaddam B.S., University of Tehran, 2001 M.S., Tehran Polytechnic, 2003 A Dissertation Proposal Submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of the University of Louisville in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Doctor of Philosophy Candidacy Department of Industrial Engineering University of Louisville Louisville, Kentucky, USA November 2008 ©Copyright 2008 by Kamran S. Moghaddam All Rights Reserved ii Preventive Maintenance and Replacement Scheduling: Models and Algorithms By Kamran S. Moghaddam B.S., University of Tehran, 2001 M.S., Tehran Polytechnic, 2003 A Dissertation Proposal Approved on November 2008 By the following Dissertation Committee Professor John S. Usher, Committee Chair Professor Gerald W. Evans Professor Gail W. DePuy Professor Sunderesh S. Heragu Professor Ali M. Shahhosseini iii TABELE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ...................................................................................................... vii LIST OF FIGURES ................................................................................................... viii 1. Introduction 1 1.1. Preventive Maintenance and Replacement Scheduling .................................. 1 1.2. Research Contributions .................................................................................... 2 1.3. Outline ................
Words: 23914 - Pages: 96
Free EssayBlackberry
... A Skeptic's Guide to Computer Models by John D. Sterman This article was written by Dr. John D. Sterman, Director of the MIT System Dynamics Group and Professor of Management Science at the Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive, Cambridge, MA 02139, USA; email: jsterman@mit.edu. Copyright © John D. Sterman, 1988, 1991. All rights reserved. This paper is reprinted from Sterman, J. D. (1991). A Skeptic's Guide to Computer Models. In Barney, G. O. et al. (eds.), Managing a Nation: The Microcomputer Software Catalog. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 209-229. An earlier version of this paper also appeared in Foresight and National Decisions: The Horseman and the Bureaucrat (Grant 1988). A S KEPTIC'S GUIDE TO COMPUTER MODELS 2 The Inevitability of Using Models........................................................................3 Mental and Computer Models..............................................................................2 The Importance of Purpose..................................................................................3 Two Kinds of Models: Optimization Versus Simulation and Econometrics.......4 Optimization.............................................................................................4 Limitations of Optimization..........................................................5 When To Use Optimization....................
Words: 14261 - Pages: 58
Premium EssayIndustrial Production
...Industrial Project Management: A Handbook of Planning, Scheduling & Evaluation Techniques Dr. Miltiadis A. Boboulos Eng. Lazar Peshev Chapter 1 Decision modelling in management 1.1. Decision Modelling Modelling decisions in management is a process of developing models reflecting the interrelations between relevant factors in a real situation. The model is reality presented in a simplified form. Modelling is a specific method and means of comprehension. It is applied in company management to study various activity alternatives using developed models. Every individual model comprises various components, variables, parameters, relations, limitations and criteria [1]. • Components correspond to the elements of the system under study. • Variables are used to describe the relations between individual components of the model. They can have more than a single value [2]. • Parameters characterize the influence that various variables have in the model. They are constant for every individual model, i.e. they have just a single value [2]. • Relations reflect the links, relations and interaction between various components, variables and parameters in the model [3]. • Limitations point out the variation limits and can be either placed in space and time, can be single-value or multi-value, one-sided or double-sided, global or local, etc [4]. • Criteria are means of evaluation, comparison and selection. They are objective and subjective, qualitative and quantitative [4]. The model...
Words: 36750 - Pages: 147
Free EssayA Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing
...A Novel Simple but Empirically Consistent Model for Stock Price and Option Pricing HUADONG(HENRY) PANG∗ Quantitative Research, J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. 277 Park Ave., New York, NY, 10017 Third draft, May 16, 2009 Abstract In this paper, we propose a novel simple but empirically very consistent stochastic model for stock price dynamics and option pricing, which not only has the same analyticity as log-normal and Black-Scholes model, but can also capture and explain all the main puzzles and phenomenons arising from empirical stock and option markets which log-normal and Black-Scholes model fail to explain. In addition, this model and its parameters have clear economic interpretations. Large sample empirical calibration and tests are performed and show strong empirical consistency with our model’s assumption and implication. Immediate applications on risk management, equity and option evaluation and trading, etc are also presented. Keywords: Nonlinear model, Random walk, Stock price, Option pricing, Default risk, Realized volatility, Local volatility, Volatility skew, EGARCH. This paper is self-funded and self-motivated. The author is currently working as a quantitative analyst at J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. All errors belong to the author. Email: henry.na.pang@jpmchase.com or hdpang@gmail.com. ∗ 1 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1374688 2 Huadong(Henry) Pang/J.P. Morgan Chase & Co. 1. Introduction The well-known log-normal model for...
Words: 7582 - Pages: 31
Premium EssayYield
...Property yields as tools for valuation and analysis Rosane Hungria-Garcia in collaboration with Hans Lind Björn Karlsson This report has been sponsored by the Real Estate Academy at the Division of Building and Real Estate Economics. Stockholm 2004 ______________________________________________________ Report No. 52 Building & Real Estate Economics Department of Infrastructure KTH Summary This project was started in order to get an overview of conceptual problems, measurement problems, theories of determinants of yields, the use of yields in different contexts and how the actors on the Swedish market looked upon yields. Important issues discussed in the report is the need for: - Conceptual clarity: A number of different yield terms exist on the market and it is very important to be clear about how the specific terms are defined. - Operational clarity: There are measurement problems both concerning rental incomes, operating and maintenance costs and property values. This means that reported yields can be “manipulated” by choosing suitable operationalisations and pushing estimations of uncertain factors in directions that are favourable to the actor in question. - Specify the purpose for which the yield should be used. The most important distinction is between using yields/income returns for valuation purposes and using yields as benchmarks or bubble indicators. In the first case various types of normalization of the net operating income can be rational. In the second...
Words: 19982 - Pages: 80
Free EssayFlaws with Black Scholes and Exotic Greeks
...Flaws with Black Scholes & Exotic Greeks Treasury Perspectives Flaws with Black Scholes & Exotic Greeks 1 Flaws with Black Scholes & Exotic Greeks 2 Flaws with Black Scholes & Exotic Greeks Dear Readers:It’s been a difficult and volatile year for companies across the Globe. We have seen numerous risk management policies failures. To name a few... UBS, JPM Morgan, Libor manipulations by European, US and Japanese banks and prominent accounting scandals like Lehman… As rightly said by Albert Einstein “We can't solve problems by using the same kind of thinking we used when we created them.” and when you can't solve the problem, then manage it and don’t be dependent upon science as Science is always wrong, it never solves a problem without creating ten more. The same is the case with Foreign Exchange Risk Management Policies (FXRM) which if can’t be managed properly then would lead to either systematic shocks or negative implications at the bottom line of the corporate, banks, FI and trading houses P&L A/cs. That is something risk management struggles with, say the experts. In Richard Meyers’ estimation, risk managers or traders do not socialize enough. “It’s all about visibility,” he said. Meyers, chairman and CEO of Richard Meyers & Associates, a talent acquisition and management firm in New Jersey, relates the story of a firm that decided to adopt an Enterprise Risk Management (ERM) strategy. Instead of appointing its risk manager to head...
Words: 9364 - Pages: 38
Premium EssayJason's
...BEA3001 Financial Management 2012-2013 Option Pricing Dr Bill Peng, CFA Today • Describe the basic characteristics of financial options • Develop the Binomial Option Pricing Model • Discuss the Put-Call Parity theorem • Introduce and apply Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model BP BEA3001 Financial Management 2 Coursework Test 1 Directions • Reminder: CW Test 2 [4pm Wed 20th Mar 2013] • CW Test 1: 6pm on Monday 26th November • Students entitled to extra time: STC/C • Surnames starting with letters “A” to “K” (inclusive): Amory Moot Room • Surnames starting with letters “L” to “W” (inclusive): STC/A • Surnames starting with letters “X” to “Z” (inclusive): STC/B BP BEA3001 Financial Management 3 Coursework Test 1 Directions cont’d • Everyone should arrive in the corridor outside either Amory Moot Room or STC A/B/C by 6:15pm and wait QUIETLY to be called into a test room • We will aim to get you settled and started as soon as possible and you will be free by 8:00pm at the latest, if all of you could kindly follow the instructions • Fair-play: breach of exam rules will be punished • You should have with you your student ID card, a note of your 2012-2013 candidate number, pencils, erasers, pens and a calculator BP BEA3001 Financial Management 4 Coursework Test 1 Directions cont’d • You should take a seat where a test paper (together with an answer booklet) has been placed, but DO NOT touch the test paper or the answer booklet until told to do...
Words: 3037 - Pages: 13
Popular Essays
Football EssayBunge Limited Review EssayMaintaining Dignity EssayHelllooooooooo EssayCase Krispy Kreme EssayEconomics EssayTừ khóa » C=25+6y1/2
-
[PDF] Mathematical Methods For Economics - Jayash Paudel
-
In The Following National Income Model, What Is/are The Endogenous ...
-
Solved Given The National Income Model Of A Hypothetical - Chegg
-
Solved In The Following National Income Model, What Is/are | Chegg ...
-
Answer To Question #146584 In Economics For Isa - Assignment Expert
-
Math For Econ - DOKUMEN.TIPS
-
Answered: Rewrite The National Income Model From… | Bartleby
-
Solutions Of Linear Differential Equations
-
[PDF] Systems Of Linear Equations; Matrices - Higher Education | Pearson
-
[PDF] Summer Math Packet Answer Key
-
[PDF] Math HL-Year 1
-
3. Find Y ° And C ° From The Following: Y=C+I_0+ - Gauthmath
-
[PDF] 8 1 71-<4 - OSTI.GOV